selling to cournot oligopolists pricing under uncertainty
play

Selling to Cournot oligopolists: pricing under uncertainty & - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

Selling to Cournot oligopolists: pricing under uncertainty & generalized mean residual life Stefanos Leonardos 1 and Costis Melolidakis National and Kapodistrian University of Athens Department of Mathematics, Division of Statistics &


  1. Selling to Cournot oligopolists: pricing under uncertainty & generalized mean residual life Stefanos Leonardos 1 and Costis Melolidakis National and Kapodistrian University of Athens Department of Mathematics, Division of Statistics & Operations Research June 2, 2018 1Supported by a fellowship of the Alexander S. Onassis Public Benefit Foundation. 1/25

  2. Overview The Model 1 Market equilibrium: existence & uniqueness 2 Market efficiency 3 Comparative statics 4 2/25

  3. Outline The Model 1 Market equilibrium: existence & uniqueness 2 Market efficiency 3 Comparative statics 4 3/25

  4. The Model I � We consider the following two-stage game (supply chain) � Upstream supplier: 1 enough capacity to cover any possible demand from the retailers 2 constant marginal cost, normalized to zero (not trivial) 3 decision variable: wholesale price r . � Downstream retailers: 1 fixed number of n ≥ 1 competing Cournot firms. 2 decision variable: order quantity to the supplier. 3 marginal cost r : wholesale price determined strategically. � Cost is endogenized in the classic Cournot competition. 4/25

  5. The Model II � Market structure: 1 single homogeneous good. 2 affine inverse demand function p = α − q ( r | α ) where α is the demand parameter and q ( r | α ) the total quantity. � Demand uncertainty: 1 demand parameter α is realized after supplier’s pricing decision but prior to retailers’ quantity decisions. 2 supplier is uncertain about the retailers’ willingness-to-pay for his price. � All the above are common knowledge among supplier & retailers. 5/25

  6. Formal setting � Extensive, 2-stage game. � Strategy sets: retailers (followers): q i : R ≥ 0 → R ≥ 0 , order-quantity for price r . supplier (Stackelberg leader): wholesale price r > 0. � Payoff functions: retailers: u i ( q | r ) = q i ( α − q ) − rq i = q i ( α − r − q ) supplier: u s ( r ) = E u s ( r | α ) = r · E q ( r | α ) � Demand uncertainty: α is realized from a: continuous cdf F , F := 1 − F , with finite ex- pectation E α < + ∞ , and nonnegative support contained in 0 ≤ α L ≤ α H ≤ + ∞ . 6/25

  7. The Outcome � Implications of our study 1 technical perspective: identify and study a mild unimodality condition that characterizes the equilibrium price and ensures a “well-behaved” non-deterministic revenue function. 2 economic perspective: obtain a mathematically tractable pricing model and perform comparative statics and market efficiency analysis via prob- abilistic tools. 7/25

  8. Outline The Model 1 Market equilibrium: existence & uniqueness 2 Market efficiency 3 Comparative statics 4 8/25

  9. Base case: deterministic demand � The supplier knows the demand parameter α : α L = α H . Proposition The complete information two-stage game has a unique subgame perfect Nash equilibrium, under which the supplier’s optimal price is r ∗ ( α ) = α/ 2 3 ( α − r ) + . and each retailer orders quantity q ∗ i ( r ) = 1 � Proof: standard. 9/25

  10. General case: stochastic demand � The supplier has incomplete information about α : α L < α H . On the equilibrium path, the supplier’s payoff is u s ( r ) = 2 3 r E ( α − r ) + , for 0 ≤ r ≤ α H . Maximization with respect to r is not straightforward u s ( r ) may not be concave, hence not unimodal. an optimal price may not even exist. requiring concavity: too restrictive. � Goal: derive a mild unimodality condition for u s ( r ) � ∞ u s ( r ) = 2 3 r E ( α − r ) + = 2 F ( u ) d u 3 r r 10/25

  11. Mean residual life (MRL) function Definition The MRL function m ( · ) of a nonnegative random variable α with cdf F and E α < + ∞ , is defined as � ∞ 1 m ( r ) := E ( α − r | α > r ) = F ( u ) d u , for r < α H F ( r ) r and m ( r ) := 0, otherwise. � Express u s ( r ) in terms of m ( r ) and differentiate u s ( r ) = 2 3 r m ( r ) F ( r ) d u s d r ( r ) = 2 3 ( m ( r ) − r ) F ( r ) = 2 � m ( r ) � − 1 F ( r ) ← FOC? 3 r r for 0 < r < α H . 11/25

  12. Generalized mean residual life (GMRL) function Definition The GMRL function m ( · ) of a nonnegative random variable α with cdf F and E α < + ∞ , is defined as ℓ ( r ) := m ( r ) , 0 < r < α H r and ℓ ( r ) := 0, otherwise. � Interpretation: expected additional demand as a percentage of the given. � Inverse of price elasticity of expected demand: � − 1 dr E q ∗ ( r | α ) � − 1 � � d − F ( r ) = e − 1 ℓ ( r ) = m ( r ) F ( r ) · r = − r · E q ∗ ( r | α ) < r > � Realistic assumption: decreasing 12/25

  13. Generalized mean residual life (GMRL) function Definition The GMRL function m ( · ) of a nonnegative random variable α with cdf F and E α < + ∞ , is defined as ℓ ( r ) := m ( r ) , 0 < r < α H r and ℓ ( r ) := 0, otherwise. � From the previous slide: d u s d r ( r ) = 2 3 ( m ( r ) − r ) F ( r ) = 2 � m ( r ) � − 1 F ( r ) 3 r r 1 m ( r ) is weakly decreasing: F is (DMRL) or 2 (i) m ( r ) / r is strictly decreasing and (ii) eventually < 1. 12/25

  14. The DGMRL & IGFR classes � The (GMRL) function is related to the (GFR) (increasing generalized failure rate) function introduced by Lariviere & Porteus (2001) g ( r ) := r h ( r ) , where h ( r ) := f ( r ) F ( r ) is the failure rate function. � GFR gives the percentage decrease in the probability of a stock out from increasing the stocking quantity by 1%. � Widely used unimodality condition: g ( r ) is increasing (IGFR). � Satisfied by most commonly used probability distributions. � IGFR ⊂ DGMRL (and more results on moments and limiting behavior). 13/25

  15. Fixed-Point Theorem Theorem If the supplier has incomplete information α ∼ F , then 1 (necessary) If an optimal price r ∗ of the supplier exists, then it satisfies the fixed point equation r ∗ = m ( r ∗ ) (1) 2 (sufficient) If F is strictly DGMRL and E α 2 is finite, then r ∗ exists and is the unique solution of (1). In this case, if 1 2 E α < α L , then r ∗ = 1 2 E α . Otherwise, r ∗ ∈ [ α L , α H ). � Generalization to any n ≥ 1 identical retailers: statement of main Theo- rem independent of n (due to second-stage equilibrium uniqueness). 14/25

  16. Outline The Model 1 Market equilibrium: existence & uniqueness 2 Market efficiency 3 Comparative statics 4 15/25

  17. On a silver platter � Probability of stockout: Theorem For any DMRL distribution F , the probability F ( r ∗ ) of an immediate stockout (no transaction) in equilibrium satisfies F ( r ∗ ) ≤ 1 − e − 1 This bound is robust: independent of the particular distribution F , and tight: attained by the exponential and, asymptotically, by a parametric Beta distribution. � Proof: immediate via MRL representation of r ∗ . � Necessity: does not extend to the class of DGMRL distributions. 16/25

  18. Price of Uncertainty � Question: for any realized demand value α how does the performance of the stochastic market compare to that of the deterministic market? Theorem � Π D � � n − 2 � . In Agg The Price of Uncertainty equals: PoU := inf α ∈ S = 1 − O Π U Agg particular, there exist demand levels for which the stochastic outperforms the deterministic market. 17/25

  19. Price of Anarchy � Question: for any realized demand value α how does the performance of the competitive market compare to that of the integrated market? Theorem The Price of Anarchy is upper-bounded: � E Π U � � n − 1 � Int PoA := sup ≤ 1 + O E Π U F ∈DG Agg � n − 2 � . If we restrict to DMRL distributions the bound improves to 1 + O � Caution: integrating the market has non-trivial implications on the infor- mation structure. � Problem: PoA is not lower-bounded by 1. 18/25

  20. Outline The Model 1 Market equilibrium: existence & uniqueness 2 Market efficiency 3 Comparative statics 4 19/25

  21. Comparative Statics � Equation r ∗ = m ( r ∗ ) allows comparative statics via stochastic orderings (partial orders with respect to various criteria on the space of all demand distributions), Shaked and Shanthikumar (2007). Lemma Let X 1 ∼ F 1 , X 2 ∼ F 2 be two nonnegative and continuous, DGMRL demand distributions with finite second moment. If X 1 � mrl X 2 , then r ∗ 1 ≤ r ∗ 2 . � In words: if market X 1 is "less than" market X 2 in a concrete stochastic sense, then wholesale prices in market X 1 are lower than in market X 2 . � Upshot: conclusions depend on the notion of market size – variability that we will employ. challenge established intuitions derived under specific instruments. 20/25

  22. Market Size � Compare markets via their size Theorem Let X 1 ∼ F 1 , X 2 ∼ F 2 be two nonnegative, DGMRL demand distributions, with finite second moments, such that X 1 � mrl X 2 . If Z satisfies some mild conditions, then r ∗ X 1 + Z ≤ r ∗ X 2 + Z . If φ is an increasing, convex function, then r ∗ φ ( X 1 ) ≤ r ∗ φ ( X 2 ) . � But: stochastically larger market does not imply a higher wholesale price. 21/25

  23. Demand Variability � Compare markets via their variability Theorem Let X 1 ∼ F 1 , X 2 ∼ F 2 be two nonnegative, DGMRL demand distributions with finite second moments and α L 1 ≤ α L 2 . If either X 1 , X 2 or both are DMRL and X 1 � ew X 2 , then r ∗ 1 ≤ r ∗ 2 . If either X 1 , X 2 or both are IFR and X 1 � disp X 2 , then r ∗ 1 ≤ r ∗ 2 . � But: a more variable market does not imply a higher wholesale price. 22/25

Download Presentation
Download Policy: The content available on the website is offered to you 'AS IS' for your personal information and use only. It cannot be commercialized, licensed, or distributed on other websites without prior consent from the author. To download a presentation, simply click this link. If you encounter any difficulties during the download process, it's possible that the publisher has removed the file from their server.

Recommend


More recommend