option pricing under a stressed beta model
play

Option Pricing Under a Stressed-Beta Model Adam Tashman in - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

Option Pricing Under a Stressed-Beta Model Adam Tashman in collaboration with Jean-Pierre Fouque University of California, Santa Barbara Department of Statistics and Applied Probability Center for Research in Financial Mathematics and


  1. Option Pricing Under a Stressed-Beta Model Adam Tashman in collaboration with Jean-Pierre Fouque University of California, Santa Barbara Department of Statistics and Applied Probability Center for Research in Financial Mathematics and Statistics November 14, 2009 1

  2. Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM) Discrete-time approach Excess return of asset R a − R f is linear function of excess return of market R M and Gaussian error term: R a − R f = β ( R M − R f ) + ǫ Beta coefficient estimated by regressing asset returns on market returns. 2

  3. Difficulties with CAPM Some difficulties with this approach, including: 1) Relationship between asset returns, market returns not always linear 2) Estimation of β from history, but future may be quite different Ultimate goal of this research is to deal with both of these issues 3

  4. Extending CAPM: Dynamic Beta Two main approaches: 1) Retain linearity, but beta changes over time; Ferson (1989), Ferson and Harvey (1991), Ferson and Harvey (1993), Ferson and Korajczyk (1995), Jagannathan and Wang (1996) 2) Nonlinear model, by way of state-switching mechanism; Fridman (1994), Akdeniz, L., Salih, A.A., and Caner (2003) ASC introduces threshold CAPM model . Our approach is related. 4

  5. Estimating Implied Beta Different approach to estimating β : look to options market • Forward-Looking Betas , 2006 P Christoffersen, K Jacobs, and G Vainberg Discrete-Time Model • Calibration of Stock Betas from Skews of Implied Volatilities , 2009 J-P Fouque, E Kollman Continuous-Time Model, stochastic volatility environment 5

  6. Example of Time-Dependent Beta Stock Industry Beta (2005-2006) Beta (2007-2008) AA Aluminum 1.75 2.23 GE Conglomerate 0.30 1.00 JNJ Pharmaceuticals -0.30 0.62 JPM Banking 0.54 0.72 WMT Retail 0.21 0.29 Larger β means greater sensitivity of stock returns relative to market returns 6

  7. Regime-Switching Model We propose a model similar to CAPM, with a key difference: When market falls below level c , slope increases by δ , where δ > 0 Thus, beta is two-valued This simple approach keeps the mathematics tractable 7

  8. Dynamics Under Physical Measure I P M t value of market at time t S t value of asset at time t dM t = µdt + σ m dW t Market Model; const vol, for now M t dS t β ( M t ) dM t = + σdZ t Asset Model S t M t β ( M t ) = β + δ I { M t <c } Brownian motions W t , Z t indep: d � W, Z � t = 0 8

  9. Dynamics Under Physical Measure I P Substituting market equation into asset equation: dS t = β ( M t ) µdt + β ( M t ) σ m dW t + σdZ t S t Asset dynamics depend on market level, market volatility σ m � β 2 ( M t ) σ 2 m + σ 2 This is a geometric Brownian motion with volatility Note this is a stochastic volatility model 9

  10. Dynamics Under Physical Measure I P Process preserves the definition of β : � � � � dS t S t , dM t β ( M t ) dM t M t + σdZ t , dM t Cov Cov M t M t � � � � = dM t dM t V ar V ar M t M t � � β ( M t ) dM t M t , dM t Cov M t � � = Since BM’s indep dM t V ar M t = β ( M t ) 10

  11. P ⋆ Dynamics Under Risk-Neutral Measure I Market is complete ( M and S both tradeable) P ⋆ defined as Thus, ∃ unique Equivalent Martingale Measure I � � � T � T � T � ( θ (1) ) 2 + ( θ (2) ) 2 � P ⋆ dI θ (2) dZ s − 1 θ (1) dW s − − P = exp ds dI 2 t t t with µ − r θ (1) = σ m r ( β ( M t ) − 1) θ (2) = σ 11

  12. P ⋆ Dynamics Under Risk-Neutral Measure I dM t rdt + σ m dW ∗ = t M t dS t rdt + β ( M t ) σ m dW ∗ t + σdZ ∗ = t S t where dW t + µ − r dW ∗ = dt t σ m dZ t + r ( β ( M t ) − 1) dZ ∗ = dt t σ P ⋆ . By Girsanov’s Thm, W ∗ t , Z ∗ t are indep Brownian motions under I 12

  13. Option Pricing P price of option with expiry T , payoff h ( S T ) Option price at time t < T is function of t , M , and S ( M , S ) Markovian Option price discounted expected payoff under risk-neutral measure P ∗ E ⋆ � � e − r ( T − t ) h ( S T ) | M t = M, S t = S P ( t, M, S ) = I 13

  14. State Variables Define new state variables: X t = log S t , ξ t = log M t Initial conditions X 0 = x , ξ 0 = ξ Dynamics are: � � r − σ 2 m dt + σ m dW ∗ dξ t = t 2 � � r − 1 2( β 2 ( e ξ t ) σ 2 m + σ 2 ) dt + β ( e ξ t ) σ m dW ∗ t + σdZ ∗ dX t = t 14

  15. State Variables WLOG, let t = 0 In integral form, � � r − σ 2 t + σ m W ∗ m ξ t = ξ + t 2 Next, consider X at expiry (integrate from 0 to T ): � � � T r − σ 2 T − σ 2 m β 2 ( e ξ t ) dt X T = x + 2 2 0 � T β ( e ξ t ) dW ∗ t + σZ ∗ + σ m T 0 15

  16. Working with X T e ξ t < c M t < c ⇒ ⇒ ξ t < log c β ( e ξ t ) = β + δ I { ξ t < log c } β ( M t ) = β + δ I { M t <c } ⇒ Using this definition for β ( e ξ t ) , X T becomes � � r − β 2 σ 2 m + σ 2 T + σ m βW ∗ T + σZ ∗ X T = x + T 2 � T � T ( δ 2 + 2 δβ ) σ 2 m I { ξ t < log c } dW ∗ − I { ξ t < log c } dt + σ m δ t 2 0 0 16

  17. Occupation Time of Brownian Motion � T Expression for X T involves integral 0 I { ξ t < log c } dt This is occupation time of Brownian motion with drift To simplify calculation, apply Girsanov to remove drift from ξ 17

  18. Occupation Time of Brownian Motion Consider new probability measure � I P defined as � � d � I P T − 1 − θW ∗ 2 θ 2 T P ⋆ = exp dI � � r − σ 2 1 m θ = σ m 2 Under this measure, ξ t is a martingale with dynamics σ m d � dξ t = W t � � r − σ 2 t + 1 d � dW ∗ m W t = dt σ m 2 18

  19. P ⋆ → � Changing Measure: I I P Since W ∗ and Z ∗ indep, Z ∗ not affected by change of measure Can replace Z ∗ with � Z Under � I P , x + A 1 T + σ m β � X T = W T � T σ � + Z T − A 2 I { ξ t < log c } dt 0 � T I { ξ t < log c } d � + σ m δ W t 0 where constants A 1 , A 2 defined as m ( β 2 − β ) + σ 2 r (1 − β ) − σ 2 A 1 = 2 δ ( δ + 2 β − 1) σ 2 m A 2 = 2 + δr 19

  20. First Passage Time Now that ξ t is driftless, easier to work with occupation time Run process until first time it hits level log c Denote this first passage time � � t ≥ 0 : � τ = inf { t ≥ 0 : ξ t = log c } = inf W t = ˜ c where c = log c − ξ ˜ σ m Density of first passage time of ξ t = ξ to level log c is � � c 2 | ˜ c | − ˜ √ p ( u ; ˜ c ) = 2 πu 3 exp , u > 0 2 u 20

  21. Including First Passage Time Information First passage time τ may happen after T , so need to be careful Can partition time horizon into two pieces: [0 , τ ∧ T ] [ τ ∧ T, T ] and τ ∧ T counts as occupation time If ξ t < log c , 21

  22. Including First Passage Time Information Incorporating this information into X T yields x + A 1 T + σ m β � W T + σ � X T = Z T � T − A 2 ( τ ∧ T ) I { ˜ c> 0 } − A 2 c } dt I { � W t < ˜ τ ∧ T � T + σ m δ � c } d � W τ ∧ T I { ˜ c> 0 } + σ m δ W t I { � W t < ˜ τ ∧ T 22

  23. Working with the Stochastic Integral c of � Stochastic integral can be re-expressed in terms of local time � L ˜ W at level ˜ c . Applying Tanaka’s formula to φ ( w ) = ( w − ˜ c ) I { w< ˜ c } between τ ∧ T and T , we get: � T c } d � W t = φ ( � W T ) − φ ( � W τ ∧ T ) + � T − � L ˜ c L ˜ c τ ∧ T . I { � W t < ˜ τ ∧ T 23

  24. Starting Level of Market: Three Cases Consider separately the three cases ξ = log c, ξ > log c , and ξ < log c (or equivalently ˜ c = 0 , ˜ c < 0 , ˜ c > 0 ) Notation for terminal log-stock price, given ξ Case ξ = log c terminal log-stock price Ψ 0 terminal log-stock price Ψ + Case ξ > log c terminal log-stock price Ψ − Case ξ < log c 24

  25. Consider Case ξ < log c as Example In this case, ˜ c > 0 and we have x + A 1 T + σ m β � W T + σ � X T = Z T � T c } dt + σ m δ � − A 2 ( τ ∧ T ) − A 2 W τ ∧ T I { � W t < ˜ τ ∧ T �� � � � � � � c } + � T − � L ˜ L ˜ c c + σ m δ W T − ˜ c c } − W τ ∧ T − ˜ c I { � I { � τ ∧ T W T < ˜ W τ ∧ T < ˜ Treat separately cases { τ < T } and { τ > T } 25

  26. Case ξ < log c , contd. • On { τ > T } , we have: x + ( A 1 − A 2 ) T + σ m ( β + δ ) � W T + σ � X T = Z T T + ( � W T , � Ψ − =: Z T ) , where lower index T + stands for τ > T Distribution of X T is given by distn of independent Gaussian r.v. � Z T , and conditional distn of � W T given { τ > T } . 26

  27. Case ξ < log c , contd. Conditional distn of � W T given { τ > T } : From Karatzas and Shreve, one easily obtains: � � � � 1 c − a )2 e − a 2 2 T − e − (2˜ � √ I P W T ∈ da, τ > T = da, a < ˜ c, 2 T 2 πT =: q T ( a ; ˜ c ) da 27

Download Presentation
Download Policy: The content available on the website is offered to you 'AS IS' for your personal information and use only. It cannot be commercialized, licensed, or distributed on other websites without prior consent from the author. To download a presentation, simply click this link. If you encounter any difficulties during the download process, it's possible that the publisher has removed the file from their server.

Recommend


More recommend