optimal portfolio liquidation with dynamic coherent risk
play

Optimal Portfolio Liquidation with Dynamic Coherent Risk Andrey - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

Optimal Portfolio Liquidation with Dynamic Coherent Risk Andrey Selivanov 1 Mikhail Urusov 2 1 Moscow State University and Gazprom Export 2 Ulm University Analysis, Stochastics, and Applications. A Conference in Honour of Walter Schachermayer


  1. Optimal Portfolio Liquidation with Dynamic Coherent Risk Andrey Selivanov 1 Mikhail Urusov 2 1 Moscow State University and Gazprom Export 2 Ulm University Analysis, Stochastics, and Applications. A Conference in Honour of Walter Schachermayer – Vienna University, July 12–16, 2010

  2. Outline Optimal Portfolio Liquidation Dynamic Risk Main Result

  3. Outline Optimal Portfolio Liquidation Dynamic Risk Main Result

  4. A trader sells x > 0 shares of a stock in an illiquid market. In selling the price falls from S − to S + = S − − 1 q x . The trader gets the payout � � S − − 1 x 2 q x � �� � average price per share instead of xS −

  5. OPL How to sell optimally X 0 shares until time N ? X 0 , N are specified by a client, X 0 is very big Time horizon is usually short A strategy is a sequence x = ( x i ) N i = 0 , where all x i ≥ 0 and � N i = 0 x i = X 0 x i means the number of shares to sell at time i , i = 0 , . . . , N X (resp., X det ) denotes the set of adapted (resp., deterministic) strategies

  6. Model for unaffected price A random walk ( S n ) (short time horizon) Model for price impact A block-shaped limit order book with infinite resilience Optimization problem Minimize a certain dynamic coherent risk measure

  7. Model for price impact Linear permanent and temporary impacts with the coefficients γ ≥ 0 resp. κ > 0 Selling x k ≥ 0 shares at times k , k = 0 , 1 , . . . : S n + = � � S n − − ( κ + γ ) x n , S n − = S n − γ � n − 1 where � i = 0 x i Payout at time n : � � S n − − κ + γ � x n x n 2 Cf. with Bertsimas and Lo (1998), Almgren and Chriss (2001) LOB with finite resilience: Obizhaeva and Wang (2005), Alfonsi, Fruth, and Schied (2010)

  8. Notation X n := X 0 − � n − 1 i = 0 x i , n = 1 , . . . , N + 1, the number of shares remaining at hand at time n − . Note that X N + 1 = 0 ( x i ) ← → ( X i ) Properties of strategies desirable for practitioners (A) Dynamic consistency (B) Presence of an intrinsic time horizon N ∗ such that N ∗ < N for small X 0 , N ∗ = N for large X 0 , N ∗ is increasing as a function of X 0 (C) Relative selling speed decreasing in the position size: x 0 X 0 decreases as a function of X 0

  9. Notation R N + revenue from the liquidation Almgren and Chriss (2001) − E R N + + λ Var R N + − − → min X det Optimal strategy is of the form X n = C 1 e − Kn − C 2 e Kn ( ∗ ) (A) + (B) − (C) − Konishi and Makimoto (2001) � − E R N + + λ Var R N + − − → min X det Optimal strategy is again of the form ( ∗ ) (A) − (B) − (C) +

  10. It would be more interesting to optimize over X rather than over X det Almgren and Lorenz (2007) − E R N + + λ Var R N + − − − → min X ( ∗ ) is no longer optimal (A)–(C): ? oneborn, and Tehranchi (2010) For U ( x ) = − e − α x , Schied, Sch¨ E U ( R N + ) − − − → max X Optimal strategy is deterministic (cf. with Schied and Sch¨ oneborn (2009)) If ( S n ) is a Gaussian random walk, then the optimal strategy is the Almgren–Chriss one with λ = α/ 2 (A) + (B) − (C) −

  11. Outline Optimal Portfolio Liquidation Dynamic Risk Main Result

  12. Static Risk (Ω , F , P ) R : Ω → R P&L of a bank How to measure risk of R ? Artzner, Delbaen, Eber, and Heath (1997, 1999): Coherent risk measures F¨ ollmer and Schied (2002), Frittelli and Rosazza Gianin (2002): Convex risk measures Notation ρ ( R ) a law invariant coherent risk measure ρ ( Law R ) := ρ ( R ) � E.g. CV @ R λ ( R ) = − E ( R | R ≤ q λ ( R )) (modulo a technicality), where q λ ( R ) is λ -quantile of R

  13. Dynamizing ρ (Ω , F , ( F n ) N n = 0 , P ) Cashflow F = ( F n ) N n = 0 : an adapted process F n means P&L of a bank at time n Need to define dynamic risk ρ ( F ) ρ ( F ) = ( ρ n ( F )) N n = 0 an adapted process ρ n ( F ) ≡ ρ ( F n , . . . , F N ) means the risk of the remaining part ( F n , . . . , F N ) of the cashflow measured at time n Define inductively: ρ N ( F ) = − F N , � � ρ n ( F ) = − F n + � ρ Law [ − ρ n + 1 ( F ) |F n ] , n = N − 1 , . . . , 0 Cf. with Riedel (2004), Cheridito and Kupper (2006), Cherny (2009)

  14. Outline Optimal Portfolio Liquidation Dynamic Risk Main Result

  15. Inputs X 0 > 0 a large number of shares to sell until time N S n = S 0 + � n i = 1 ξ i , where ( ξ i ) iid F n = σ ( ξ 1 , . . . , ξ n ) , where F 0 = triv A strategy is an ( F n ) -adapted sequence x = ( x i ) N i = 0 , where all x i ≥ 0 and � N i = 0 x i = X 0 X (resp., X det ) denotes the set of all (resp., deterministic) strategies → ( X i ) , where X n = X 0 − � n − 1 ( x i ) ← i = 0 x i

  16. Problem Settings i = 0 define the cashflow F x by Setting 1 For a strategy x = ( x i ) N � � S n − γ � n − 1 F x i = 0 x i − κ + γ n = x n 2 x n , n = 0 , . . . , N . The problem: ρ 0 ( F x ) − → min over x ∈ X Setting 2 For a strategy x define G x by G x 0 = 0 and � � 2 − γ � n − 2 S n − 1 + ξ n i = 0 x i − κ + γ G x n = x n − 1 2 x n − 1 , n = 1 , . . . , N + 1 . The problem: ρ 0 ( G x ) − → min over x ∈ X

  17. Main Result Standing assumption 0 < � ρ ( Law ξ ) < ∞ Set a := � ρ ( Law ξ ) /κ , so a > 0 Theorem Optimal strategy is the same in both settings. Moreover, it is deterministic and given by the formulas � N ∗ � X 0 i = 0 , . . . , N ∗ , x i = N ∗ + 1 + a 2 − i , i = N ∗ + 1 , . . . , N , x i = 0 , where � � � ceil − 1 + 1 + 8 X 0 / a N ∗ = N ∧ − 1 2 with ceil y denoting the minimal integer d such that y ≤ d

  18. Discussion If we maximized over X det rather than over X , then the optimizer would be the same in both settings. This is not clear a priori when we maximize over X The proof consists of two parts: first we prove that optimizing over X does not do a better job, than optimizing over X det , and then perform just a deterministic optimization Cf. with Alfonsi, Fruth, and Schied (2010), Schied, Sch¨ oneborn, and Tehranchi (2010), where the optimal strategies are also deterministic Why is the optimal strategy deterministic? Because here liquidity ( κ ) is deterministic Cf. with Fruth, Sch¨ oneborn, and Urusov (2010), where stochastic liquidity leads to stochastic optimal strategies

  19. Remarks ◮ (A) + (B) + (C) + (recall “ + − − ” for the Almgren–Chriss strategy) ◮ ( X n ) parabola vs. X n = C 1 e − Kn − C 2 e Kn (Almgren–Chriss is now a benchmark for practitioners) ◮ Setting N = ∞ (time horizon is not specified by the client) we get a strategy with a purely intrinsic time horizon N ∗ . Cf. with Almgren (2003), Sch¨ oneborn (2008) ◮ a ↑ leads to a quicker liquidation in the beginning = ⇒ reasonable dependence of the liquidation strategy on volatility risk ( � ρ ( Law ξ ) ) and on liquidity risk ( κ )

  20. Thank you for your attention!

  21. Possible Generalizations ◮ More general price impact? Optimal strategies are again deterministic ◮ Convex risk measure ρ ? Optimal strategies are again deterministic, however, different in Settings 1 and 2 Typically (A) + (B) − Also (C) − in an example with entropic risk measure, which was worked out explicitly

  22. Alfonsi, A., A. Fruth, and A. Schied (2010). Optimal execution strategies in limit order books with general shape functions. Quantitative Finance 10 (2), 143–157. Almgren, R. (2003). Optimal execution with nonlinear impact functions and trading-enhanced risk. Applied Mathematical Finance 10 , 1–18. Almgren, R. and N. Chriss (2001). Optimal execution of portfolio transactions. Journal of Risk 3 , 5–39. Almgren, R. and J. Lorenz (2007). Adaptive arrival price. In Algorithmic Trading III: Precision, Control, Execution . Ed.: Brian R. Bruce, Institutional Investor Journals. Artzner, P ., F . Delbaen, J.-M. Eber, and D. Heath (1997). Thinking coherently.

  23. Risk 10 (11), 68–71. Artzner, P ., F . Delbaen, J.-M. Eber, and D. Heath (1999). Coherent measures of risk. Math. Finance 9 (3), 203–228. Bertsimas, D. and A. Lo (1998). Optimal control of execution costs. Journal of Financial Markets 1 , 1–50. F¨ ollmer, H. and A. Schied (2002). Convex measures of risk and trading constraints. Finance Stoch. 6 (4), 429–447. Frittelli, M. and E. Rosazza Gianin (2002). Putting order in risk measures. Journal of Banking an Finance 26 (7), 1473–1486. Konishi, H. and N. Makimoto (2001). Optimal slice of a block trade. Journal of Risk 3 (4).

  24. Obizhaeva, A. and J. Wang (2005). Optimal trading strategy and supply/demand dynamics. Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=686168. Schied, A. and T. Sch¨ oneborn (2009). Risk aversion and the dynamics of optimal liquidation strategies in illiquid markets. Finance Stoch. 13 (2), 181–204. Schied, A., T. Sch¨ oneborn, and M. Tehranchi (2010). Optimal basket liquidation for CARA investors is deterministic. To appear in Applied Mathematical Finance .

Download Presentation
Download Policy: The content available on the website is offered to you 'AS IS' for your personal information and use only. It cannot be commercialized, licensed, or distributed on other websites without prior consent from the author. To download a presentation, simply click this link. If you encounter any difficulties during the download process, it's possible that the publisher has removed the file from their server.

Recommend


More recommend