on validity of a singular perturbation expansion of
play

On validity of a singular perturbation expansion of European options - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

On validity of a singular perturbation expansion of European options and implied volatility Masaaki Fukasawa CSFI, Osaka Univ. 1 [Stochastic volatility model: Notation] Suppose that S t : an asset price, Z t = log( S t ) : log price, r : risk


  1. On validity of a singular perturbation expansion of European options and implied volatility Masaaki Fukasawa CSFI, Osaka Univ. 1

  2. [Stochastic volatility model: Notation] Suppose that S t : an asset price, Z t = log( S t ) : log price, r : risk free rate, W , W ′ : Brownian motions, � W , W ′ � t = ρ t , dZ t = ( r − ϕ ( X t ) 2 / 2) dt + ϕ ( X t ) dW t , dX t = b ( X t ) dt + c ( X t ) dW ′ t under risk neutral probability P . The option price for payoff h is given as P ( t , z , x ) = E [ e − r ( T − t ) h ( S T ) | Z t = z , X t = x ] . 2

  3. In a stochastic volatility model, stylized facts such as • the (Black-Scholes) implied volatility skew/smile, • time varying volatility, • leverage effect, • mean-reverting volatility are explained. It is a natural extension of the Black-Scholes model, including the Heston model, SABR model. Unfortunately, no simple analytic formula for the option prices is available in general. 3

  4. [Singular perturbation expansion] Fouque, Papanicolaou and Sircar (2000): consider dZ t = ( r − ϕ ( X t ) 2 / 2) + ϕ ( X t ) dW t , dX t = − aX t − b dt + Λ ( X t ) √ ǫ dt + c √ ǫ dW ′ t ǫ where ǫ is small. They obtained, by a formal calculation, that P ( t , z , x ) = P 0 ( t , z ) + √ ǫ P 1 ( t , z ) + O ( ǫ ) , where P 0 is the Black-Scholes price. 4

  5. The validity of the singular perturbation expansion is proved by • Fouque, Papanicolaou, Sircar and Solna (2003) • Conlon and Sullivan (2005) - higher order expansion for call option • Khasminskii and Yin (2005) - ergodic diffusion on compact set and smooth payoff • Fukasawa (2008) - general ergodic diffusion and payoff - Edgeworth expansion for ergodic diffusions 5

  6. [Extended fast mean-reverting model] More generally, consider dZ t = ( r − ϕ ( X t ) 2 / 2) dt + ϕ ( X t ) dW t , dX t = b ( X t ) + Λ ǫ ( X t ) dt + c ( X t ) √ ǫ dW ′ t , ǫ where Λ ǫ → 0 (in a weak sense) as ǫ → 0 . W ′ = ǫ − 1 / 2 W ′ Intuition: put ˆ X t = X ǫ t and ˆ ǫ t . Let Λ ǫ = 0 for brevity. Then X t /ǫ ) 2 / 2) dt + ϕ ( ˆ dZ t = ( r − ϕ ( ˆ X t /ǫ ) dW t , W ′ d ˆ X t = b ( ˆ X t ) dt + c ( ˆ X t ) d ˆ t . Notice that the law of ˆ X does not depend on ǫ . 6

  7. Intuition (continued): putting W ′ = ǫ − 1 / 2 W ′ W = ǫ − 1 / 2 W ǫ t , ˆ ˆ ˆ X t = X ǫ t , ǫ t , we have ∫ t /ǫ ∫ t /ǫ X s ) 2 / 2) ds + √ ǫ ( r − ϕ ( ˆ ϕ ( ˆ X s ) d ˆ Z t = Z 0 + ǫ W s , 0 0 where W ′ d ˆ X t = b ( ˆ X t ) dt + c ( ˆ X t ) d ˆ t . W ′ ) does not depend on ǫ , so that Note that the law of ( ˆ X , ˆ W , ˆ ∫ t /ǫ X s ) 2 ds → t π [ ϕ 2 ] as ǫ → 0 ϕ ( ˆ � Z � t = ǫ 0 for the ergodic distribution π of ˆ X . Consequently, by the martingale CLT, √ Z t ⇒ Z 0 + ( r − π [ ϕ 2 ] / 2) t + π [ ϕ 2 ] W t . 7

  8. [Edgeworth expansion for ergodic diffusions: Fukasawa(2008, PTRF)] For a diffusion X with scale function S : ∫ x { } ∫ b ( y ) dx S ′ ( x ) = s ( x ) , s ( x ) = exp − 2 c ( y ) 2 dy , M = c ( x ) 2 s ( x ) < ∞ x 0 we have ∫ T √ I T [ ϕ ] = 1 T ( I T [ ϕ ] − π [ ϕ ]) ⇒ N (0 , σ 2 ) , ϕ ( X t ) dt → π [ ϕ ] , T 0 where π ( dx ) / dx = 1 / Mc ( x ) 2 s ( x ) . As a refinement of this CLT, we can show √ E [ H ( T ( A ( I T [ ϕ ]) − A ( π [ ϕ ])))] ∫ ∫ H ( w ) N ( dw ) + T − 1 / 2 H ( w ) p ( w ) N ( dw ) + O ( T − 1 ) = under a moment condition and a smoothness condition. 8

  9. [First result: Edgeworth approach] Recall that dZ t = ( r − ϕ ( X t ) 2 / 2) dt + ϕ ( X t ) dW t , dX t = ǫ − 1 b ǫ ( X t ) dt + ǫ − 1 / 2 c ( X t ) dW ′ t , where b ǫ = b + Λ ǫ . • the state space of X is supposed to be R . • assume that sup ǫ ≥ 0 | b ǫ | , c , 1 / c , ϕ are locally bounded. • the option price for payoff h is given as P ( t , z , x ) = E [ e − r ( T − t ) h ( S T ) | Z t = z , X t = x ] . 9

  10. ∫ x dy ϕ ( y ) / c ( y ) , [Assumptions] L ǫ ; the generator of ˆ X , ˆ X t = X ǫ t ψ ( x ) = • L ǫ ψ → L 0 ψ on an interval I and L 0 ψ is continuous on I , • L 0 ψ is not constant on I , • there exist κ ± > 0 such that 1 + ϕ ( x ) 2 1 + ϕ ( x ) 2 γ ± > 2 κ ± , sup e κ + x c ( x ) 2 < ∞ , sup e − κ − x c ( x ) 2 < ∞ , x ≥ 0 x ≤ 0 where b ǫ ( x ) b ǫ ( x ) γ + = − lim sup c ( x ) 2 , γ − = lim inf c ( x ) 2 . x →−∞ ,ǫ → 0 x →∞ ,ǫ → 0 10

  11. [Theorem] If h is bounded, then for every ( t , z , x ) , P ( t , z , x ) = P 0 ( t , z ) + √ ǫ P 1 ( t , z ) + O ( ǫ ) , where P 0 is the Black-Scholes price with volatility σ = √ π ǫ [ ϕ 2 ] ; h (exp( z + ( r − σ 2 / 2) τ + σ √ τ w )) N ( dw ) , ∫ P 0 ( t , z ) = e − r τ τ = T − t , and h (exp( z + ( r − σ 2 / 2) τ + σ √ τ w )) ∫ P 1 ( t , z ) = e − r τ  1 − w 2 + w 3 − 3 w   × δ    N ( dw ) ,  σ √ τ  σ 2   ∫ ∞ ∫ x ( ϕ ( y ) 2 − σ 2 ) π ǫ ( dy ) ϕ ( x ) δ = − ρ c ( x ) dx . −∞ −∞ 11

  12. [Corollary] The put option price admits P ( t , z , x ) = P 0 ( t , z ) − δ √ ǫ σ 2 e z φ ( d 1 ) d 2 + O ( ǫ ) , where P 0 is the Black-Scholes put price, and ( d 1 , d 2 ) is the usual one with σ . The Black-Scholes implied volatility IV admits δ √ ǫ d 2 IV = σ − + O ( ǫ ) . σ 2 √ T − t Note that log( K / S t ) IV = c 1 + c 2 + O ( ǫ ) T − t for strike K , where c 1 and c 2 are constants of O ( √ ǫ ) and O (1) respectively. 12

  13. [Example: the Heston model] √ dZ t = ( r − V t / 2) dt + V t dW t , dt + c √ V t dV t = − aV t − b √ ǫ dW ′ t ǫ with � W , W ′ � t = ρ t . We have σ 2 = b / a and δ = ρ bc / 2 a 2 , so that a − ρ c √ ǫ d 2 √ b IV = √ + O ( ǫ ) . 2 a T − t 13

  14. [Alternative conditions for a diffusion being not exponentially mixing] • L ǫ ψ → L 0 ψ on an interval I and L 0 ψ is continuous on I , • L 0 ψ is not constant on I , • there exist p ≥ 0 such that 1 + ϕ ( x ) 2 | x | p − 2 c ( x ) 2 < ∞ , 2 γ + 1 > 4 p , lim sup | x |→∞ where xb ǫ ( x ) γ = − lim sup c ( x ) 2 . x →∞ ,ǫ → 0 The same conclusion as before is obtained under these conditions. 14

  15. [What is new?] • a probabilistic approach. • the Heston model (or, a model with irregular coefficients) is incorporated. • digital options (or, irregular payoff functions) are incorporated. • volatility process X with slow decay of the autocorrelation function is in- corporated. For example, X t dX t = − α + β dW t . 1 + X 2 t 15

  16. [Second result: martingale approach] Let us consider a more general model for Z = log( S ) , Z = Z 0 + A + M + g · W + h · C , where M is a local martingale, g and h are adapted cag processes, C is a time-changed compound Poisson process with intensity Λ , W is a std BM in- dependent ( M , g , h , Λ ) , ∫ t ∫ t ∫ A t = rt − 1 2 � M � t − 1 ( e h s z − 1) ν ( dz ) Λ ( ds ) . | g s | 2 ds − 2 0 0 R We consider the following perturbation: M = M n , g = g n , h = h n , Λ = Λ n , ν = ν n with � Z � T / Σ n → T for a sequence Σ n as n → ∞ so that the martingale CLT is applied. Hence, the Black-Scholes model is recovered as n → ∞ . 16

  17. In this framework, putting r n = ǫ 2 n → 0 , • slowly varying volatility: (Sircar, Lee, ...) dX n t = ( r n b 1 ( X n t ) + r 2 n b 2 ( X n t )) dt + r n c ( X n t ) dW t , • small volatility of volatility: (Hull and White, Lewis, S ø rensen et.al., ..) dX n t = b ( X n t ) dt + r n c ( X n t ) dW t , • fast mean-reverting: (Fouque et.al., Khasminskii et.al., Fukasawa ) t = r − 2 t ) dt + r − 1 t ) dt + r − 1 dX n n b ( X n n λ ( X n n c ( X n t ) dW t , are included. 17

  18. [Theorem] Under several conditions, we have for any bounded function H , ∫ √ E [ H ( Z T )] = H ( rT − Σ n / 2 + Σ n z ) φ n ( z ) dz + o ( r n ) R with a sequence r n → 0 as n → ∞ , ( ) 1 + r n γ + 1 { { β ( z 2 − 1) + ( z 3 − 3 z ) φ n ( z ) = φ ( z ) 3 α 2 √ Σ n {( ) }}} z + γ ( z 2 − 1) √ − Σ n β + 3 α . Here α, β, γ are functions of T . [Proof] Apply Yoshida’s formula for martingale expansion. 18

  19. [Corollary] The put option price e − rT E [( K − S T ) + | S 0 = S ] is expanded as √ √ { } P 0 ( σ n ) + 1 β − γ d 2 − 1 2 r n σ n TS φ ( d 1 ) 3 α ( d 2 − σ n T ) + o ( r n ) , where P 0 ( σ n ) is the Black-Scholes put price with volatility σ n and σ 2 n T = Σ n The Black-Scholes implied volatility IV is expanded as √ { { }} 1 + r n β − γ d 2 − 1 σ n 3 α ( d 2 − σ n T ) + o ( r n ) . 2 Note that IV = c 1 log( K / S 0 ) + c 2 + o ( r n ) for strike K , where c 1 and c 2 are functions of T , of O ( r n ) and O (1) respectively. 19

  20. [What is new?] • a probabilistic approach. • various perturbations are treated in a unified way. • non-Markovian model is incorporated. • jump is also incorporated. • multi-dimensional volatility process is incorporated. Remark: the Edgeworth approach is more useful as far as considering fast mean reverting volatility with one-dimensional diffusion. 20

Download Presentation
Download Policy: The content available on the website is offered to you 'AS IS' for your personal information and use only. It cannot be commercialized, licensed, or distributed on other websites without prior consent from the author. To download a presentation, simply click this link. If you encounter any difficulties during the download process, it's possible that the publisher has removed the file from their server.

Recommend


More recommend