on multi period risk functionals
play

On Multi-Period Risk Functionals Georg Ch. Pflug September 25, 2008 - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

On Multi-Period Risk Functionals Georg Ch. Pflug September 25, 2008 Georg Ch. Pflug On Multi-Period Risk Functionals Why to measure risk/acceptability In longer term planning such as portfolio planning, pension fund management,


  1. On Multi-Period Risk Functionals Georg Ch. Pflug September 25, 2008 Georg Ch. Pflug On Multi-Period Risk Functionals

  2. Why to measure risk/acceptability In longer term planning such as ◮ portfolio planning, ◮ pension fund management, ◮ electricity portfolio management, ◮ gas portfolio management, we have to find decision strategies in a random environment. A good decision aims at maximizing the expected return among all acceptable decisions. What is the overall expected return is clear. The overall acceptability is measured by a functional A ( Y 1 , . . . , Y T ) from which we require that is is larger than some threshold. Georg Ch. Pflug On Multi-Period Risk Functionals

  3. A typical multi-period problem ξ = ( ξ 1 , . . . , ξ T ) a scenario process x = ( x 0 , . . . , x T − 1 ) the decision process Y t = H t ( x 0 , . . . , x t − 1 ; ξ 1 , . . . , ξ t ) the generated income process T � Maximize E [ Y t ] t =1 subject to A t ( Y 1 , . . . , Y t ) ≥ q t t = 1 , . . . , T x ✁ F F x ∈ X observation of observation of observation of the r.v. ξ 1 the r.v. ξ 2 the r.v. ξ 3 ❄ ❄ ❄ ❄ t = t 1 t = t 2 t = t 3 t = 0 decision decision decision decision x 0 x 1 x 2 x 3 Georg Ch. Pflug On Multi-Period Risk Functionals

  4. What is a single -period risk/acceptability measure? A mapping A : L p (Ω , F , P ) → R is called acceptability functional if it satisfies the following conditions for all Y , ˜ Y ∈ Y , c ∈ R , λ ∈ [0 , 1]: (A1) A ( Y + c ) = A ( Y ) + c ( translation-equivariance ), (A1’) There is a linear subspace W ⊆ L p and a function Z ∗ ∈ L q ( F ) (1 / p + 1 / q = 1) such that for W ∈ W A ( W ) = E ( W Z ∗ ) . It then follows that A ( Y + W ) = A ( Y )+ E ( W Z ∗ ) , ( the ( W , Z ∗ ) translation property ) . (A2) A ( λ Y + (1 − λ ) ˜ Y ) ≥ λ A ( Y ) + (1 − λ ) A ( ˜ Y ) ( concavity ), (A3) Y ≤ ˜ Y implies A ( Y ) ≤ A ( ˜ Y ) ( monotonicity ). Georg Ch. Pflug On Multi-Period Risk Functionals

  5. An acceptability functional A is called ◮ version-independent (law-invariant) if A ( Y ) depends only on the distribution function G Y ( u ) = P { Y ≤ u } Given an acceptability functional A , the mappings ρ := −A and D := E − A are called risk capital and deviation risk functional , respectively. Georg Ch. Pflug On Multi-Period Risk Functionals

  6. By the Fenchel-Moreau Theorem, every concave upper semicontinuous (u.s.c.) functional A on Y has a representation of the form A ( Y ) = inf { E ( Y Z ) − A + ( Z ) : Z ∈ Z} , (1) where A + ( Z ) = inf { E ( Y Z ) − A ( Y ) : Y ∈ Y} . We call (1) a dual representation . Let dom ( A + ) = { Z : A + ( Z ) > −∞} . Then ◮ A is monotonic, iff dom ( A + ) ⊆ L + q ◮ A has the ( W , Z ∗ ) translation property (A1’), iff dom ( A + ) ⊆ W ⊥ + Z ∗ ◮ A is positively homogeneous, iff A + takes only the values 0 and −∞ Georg Ch. Pflug On Multi-Period Risk Functionals

  7. Examples for acceptability functionals ◮ The expectation. A ( Y ) = E ( Y ). � α ◮ The Average Value-at-Risk. A V @ R α ( Y ) = 1 0 G − 1 Y ( p ) dp . α � 1 0 G − 1 ◮ The distortion functional. A ( Y ) = Y ( p ) k ( p ) dp . ◮ Risk corrected expectation. ◮ E ( Y ) − δ S td − ( Y ) ◮ E ( Y ) − δ Gini( Y ) ◮ E ( Y ) − δ Mad( Y ) Georg Ch. Pflug On Multi-Period Risk Functionals

  8. Examples for dual representations Let h be a convex, nonnegative function satisfying h (0) = 0 and let h ∗ ( v ) = sup { uv − h ( u ) : u ∈ R } be its Fenchel dual. primal dual A ( Y ) = E Y − E [ h ( Y − E Y )] A ( Y ) = inf { E ( Y Z ) + D h ∗ ( Z ) : E Z = 1 } D h ∗ ( Z ) = inf { E [ h ∗ ( Z − a )] : a ∈ R } A ( Y ) = inf { E ( Y Z ) + E ( h ∗ (1 − Z )) : E ( Z ) = 1 } A ( Y ) = E Y − inf { E [ h ( Y − a )] : a ∈ R } A ( Y ) = E ( Y ) − M h ( Y − E Y ) A ( Y ) = inf { E ( Y Z ) : E ( Z ) = 1 , inf a { D ∗ h ∗ ( Z − a ) } ≤ 1 } M h ( Y ) = inf { a ≥ 0 : E [ h ( Y a )] ≤ h (1) } D ∗ h ∗ ( Z ) = sup { E ( Z V ) : E [ h ∗ ( V )] ≤ h ∗ (1) } . � 1 0 G − 1 A ( Y ) = ( p ) k ( p ) dp A ( Y ) = inf { E ( Y Z ) : E ( φ ( Z )) ≤ � φ ( k ( u )) du , φ convex , φ (0) = 0 } , Y k nonnegative, monotonic, bounded Georg Ch. Pflug On Multi-Period Risk Functionals

  9. A special case is the Average Value-at-Risk A V @ R α � 1 primal: A V @ R α ( Y ) = 1 G − 1 Y ( p ) dp = max { a − E ([ Y − a ] − ) : a ∈ R } α 0 dual: A V @ R α ( Y ) = inf { E ( Y Z ) : 0 ≤ Z ≤ 1 /α, E ( Z ) = 1 } . Georg Ch. Pflug On Multi-Period Risk Functionals

  10. Conditional acceptability functionals Let F 1 be a σ -field contained in F . A mapping A F 1 : L p ( F ) → L p ( F 1 ) is called conditional acceptability mapping if the following conditions are satisfied for all Y , λ ∈ [0 , 1]: (CA1) A F 1 ( Y + Y (1) ) = A F 1 ( Y ) + Y (1) for Y (1) ✁ F 1 ( predictable translation-equivariance); (CA2) A F 1 ( λ Y + (1 − λ ) ˜ Y ) ≥ λ A F 1 ( Y ) + (1 − λ ) A F 1 ( ˜ Y ) ( concavity ), (CA3) Y ≤ ˜ Y implies A F 1 ( Y ) ≤ A F 1 ( ˜ Y ) ( monotonicity ). Georg Ch. Pflug On Multi-Period Risk Functionals

  11. Theorem. A mapping A F 1 is a conditional acceptability mapping if and only if for all B ∈ F 1 the functional Y �→ E ( A F 1 ( Y )1 l B ) is an acceptability functional, which has the ( L p ( F 1 ) , 1 l B ) translation property, that is E ( A F 1 ( Y + Y (1) )1 l B ) + E ( Y (1) 1 l B ) = E ( A F 1 ( Y )1 l B ) for all Y (1) ∈ L p ( F 1 ). Georg Ch. Pflug On Multi-Period Risk Functionals

  12. The conditional Average Value-at-Risk. For Y ∈ L 1 , A V @ R α ( Y |F 1 ) is defined on L 1 ( F ) by the relation l B ) : 0 ≤ Z ≤ 1 E ( A V @ R α ( Y |F 1 )1 l B ) = inf { E ( Y Z 1 α, E ( Z |F 1 ) = 1 } . ( B ∈ F 1 ). There is a version such that α �→ A V @ R α ( Y |F 1 ) is monotonically increasing a.s. for α ∈ (0 , 1]. The L 1 space is an order complete Banach lattice, which implies that every set of elements from L 1 , which is bounded from below has an infimum. Denote this infimum by inf . We may also write A V @ R α ( Y |F 1 ) = inf { E ( Y Z |F 1 ) : 0 ≤ Z ≤ 1 α, E ( Z |F 1 ) = 1 } . Georg Ch. Pflug On Multi-Period Risk Functionals

  13. From unconditional to conditional functionals By considering the trivial σ -algebra F 0 = ( ∅ , Ω) one may specialize every conditional acceptability mapping to an ordinary acceptability measure. Conversely, one may lift version-independent acceptability functionals to conditional acceptability mappings: Assume that A is defined by A ( Y ) = inf { E ( Y Z ) − A + ( Z ) : E ( Z ) = 1 , Z ≥ 0 , Z ∈ Z} , where A + is the conjugate functional and Z is the set of subgradients. Georg Ch. Pflug On Multi-Period Risk Functionals

  14. Conditional subgradient sets and conjugates Assume that the subgradient set of A is defined by Z = { Z : Z ≥ 0 , Z ∈ A a . s ., sup E ( φ c ( Z )) ≤ 0 , inf d ∈ D E ( ψ d ( Z )) ≤ 0 } c ∈ C where C and D are countable index sets. Then the conditional subgradient set is Z ( F 1 ) = { Z : E ( Z |F 1 ) = 1 , Z ≥ 0 , Z ∈ A a . s ., E ( φ c ( Z ) |F 1 ) ≤ 0 , a . s ., d ∈ D E ( ψ d ( Z ) |F 1 ) ≤ 0 , a . s . } . sup inf c ∈ C In many cases the conditional conjugate A + ( ·|F 1 ) may be found in a direct way. Georg Ch. Pflug On Multi-Period Risk Functionals

  15. Examples for conditional acceptability functionals unconditional: A ( Y ) = inf { E ( Y Z ) + inf { E [ h ∗ ( Z − a )] : a ∈ R } : E Z = 1 } conditional: A ( Y |F 1 ) = inf { E ( Y Z |F 1 ) + inf { E [ h ∗ ( Z − a ) |F 1 ] : a ✁ F 1 } : E ( Z |F 1 ) = 1 } unconditional: A ( Y ) = inf { E ( Y Z ) + E ( h ∗ (1 − Z )) : E ( Z ) = 1 } conditional: A ( Y |F 1 ) = inf { E ( Y Z |F 1 ) + E ( h ∗ (1 − Z ) |F 1 ) : E ( Z ) = 1 } unconditional: A ( Y ) = inf { E ( Y Z ) : E ( Z ) = 1 , inf a { sup { E [( Z − a ) V ] : E [ h ( V ) |F 1 ] ≤ h (1) } ≤ 1 } conditional: A ( Y |F 1 ) = inf { E ( Y Z |F 1 ) : E ( Z |F 1 ) = 1 , inf a { sup { E [( Z − a ) V |F 1 ] : E [ h ( V ) |F 1 ] ≤ h (1) } ≤ 1 } � unconditional: A ( Y ) = inf { E ( Y Z ) : E ( φ ( Z )) ≤ φ ( k ( u )) du , φ convex , φ (0) = 0 } � conditional: A ( Y |F 1 ) = inf { E ( Y Z |F 1 ) : E ( φ ( Z ) |F 1 ) ≤ φ ( k ( u )) du , φ convex , φ (0) = 0 } Georg Ch. Pflug On Multi-Period Risk Functionals

  16. Multi-period acceptability functionals Let Y = ( Y 1 , . . . , Y T ) be an income process on some probability space (Ω , F , P ) and let F F = ( F 0 , . . . , F T ) denote a filtration which models the available information over time, where F 0 = {∅ , Ω } , F T = F , F t ⊆ F t +1 ⊆ F , and Y t is F t measurable for every t = 1 , . . . , T . Let Y ⊆ × T t =1 L 1 (Ω , F , P ) be a linear space of income processes Y = ( Y 1 , . . . , Y T ), which are all adapted to F F . Definition. A multi-period functional A with values A ( Y ; F F ) is called multi-period acceptability functional , if satisfies (MA0) Information monotonicity. If Y ∈ Y and F t ⊆ F ′ t , for all t , then A ( Y ; F 0 , . . . , F T − 1 ) ≤ A ( Y ; F ′ 0 , . . . , F ′ T − 1 ) . Georg Ch. Pflug On Multi-Period Risk Functionals

Download Presentation
Download Policy: The content available on the website is offered to you 'AS IS' for your personal information and use only. It cannot be commercialized, licensed, or distributed on other websites without prior consent from the author. To download a presentation, simply click this link. If you encounter any difficulties during the download process, it's possible that the publisher has removed the file from their server.

Recommend


More recommend