markowitz portfolio theory
play

Markowitz Portfolio Theory What If Side Effects . . . Helps - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

The Main Idea Behind . . . Example A Similar Idea Works . . . How Markowitz . . . Markowitz Portfolio Theory What If Side Effects . . . Helps Decrease Medicines Applications to . . . This Idea Also Works! Side Effect and Speed Up


  1. The Main Idea Behind . . . Example A Similar Idea Works . . . How Markowitz . . . Markowitz Portfolio Theory What If Side Effects . . . Helps Decrease Medicines’ Applications to . . . This Idea Also Works! Side Effect and Speed Up References to a . . . Reference to a Neural . . . Machine Learning Home Page Title Page Thongchai Dumrongpokaphan 1 and Vladik Kreinovich 2 ◭◭ ◮◮ 1 Faculty of Science, Chiang Mai University ◭ ◮ Chiang Mai, Thailand, tcd43@hotmail.com 2 University of Texas at El Paso, USA, vladik@utep.edu Page 1 of 32 Go Back Full Screen Close Quit

  2. The Main Idea Behind . . . Example 1. The Main Idea Behind Markowitz Portfolio A Similar Idea Works . . . Theory How Markowitz . . . • In his Nobel-prize winning paper, H. M. Markowitz What If Side Effects . . . proposed a method for selecting an optimal portfolio. Applications to . . . This Idea Also Works! • To explain the main ideas behind his method, let us References to a . . . start with a simple case when: Reference to a Neural . . . – we have n independent financial instrument, each Home Page – with a known expected return-on-investment µ i Title Page – and with a known standard deviation σ i . ◭◭ ◮◮ • We can combine these instruments, by allocating the ◭ ◮ part w i of our investment to the i -th instrument. Page 2 of 32 � n • Here, we have w i ≥ 0 and w i = 1. Go Back i =1 Full Screen Close Quit

  3. The Main Idea Behind . . . Example 2. Markowitz Portfolio Theory (cont-d) A Similar Idea Works . . . • For each portfolio, we can determine the expected re- How Markowitz . . . turn on investment µ and the standard deviation σ : What If Side Effects . . . Applications to . . . n n � � w i · µ i and σ 2 = w 2 i · σ 2 µ = i . This Idea Also Works! i =1 i =1 References to a . . . Reference to a Neural . . . • Some of such portfolios are less risky – i.e., have smaller Home Page σ – but have a smaller µ . Title Page • Other portfolios have a larger expected return on in- ◭◭ ◮◮ vestment but are more risky. ◭ ◮ • We can therefore formulate two possible problems. Page 3 of 32 Go Back Full Screen Close Quit

  4. The Main Idea Behind . . . Example 3. Markowitz Portfolio Theory (cont-d) A Similar Idea Works . . . • The first problem is when we want to achieve a certain How Markowitz . . . expected return on investment µ ; What If Side Effects . . . Applications to . . . – out of all possible portfolios that provide such ex- This Idea Also Works! pected return on investment, References to a . . . – we want to find the portfolio for which the risk σ Reference to a Neural . . . is the smallest possible. Home Page • The second problem is when we know the maximum Title Page amount of risk σ that we can tolerate. ◭◭ ◮◮ • There are several different portfolios that provide the ◭ ◮ allowed amount of risk; Page 4 of 32 – out of all such portfolios, Go Back – we would like to select the one that provides the largest possible return on investment. Full Screen Close Quit

  5. The Main Idea Behind . . . Example 4. Example A Similar Idea Works . . . • Let us consider the simplest case, when all n instru- How Markowitz . . . ments have the same µ and σ : What If Side Effects . . . Applications to . . . µ 1 = . . . = µ n , σ 1 = . . . = σ n . This Idea Also Works! • In this case, the problem is completely symmetric with References to a . . . respect to permutations. Reference to a Neural . . . Home Page • Thus, the optimal portfolio should be symmetric too. Title Page • So, all the parts must be the same: w 1 = . . . = w n . ◭◭ ◮◮ � n w i = 1, this implies that w 1 = . . . = w n = 1 • Since n . ◭ ◮ i =1 • For these values w i , the expected return on investment Page 5 of 32 is the same µ = µ i , but the risk decreases: Go Back n � i = n · 1 1 = 1 1 , hence σ = σ 1 σ 2 = w 2 i · σ 2 n 2 · σ 2 n · σ 2 √ n. Full Screen i =1 Close Quit

  6. The Main Idea Behind . . . Example 5. What We Can Conclude From This Example A Similar Idea Works . . . A natural conclusion is that: How Markowitz . . . What If Side Effects . . . • if we diversify our portfolio, i.e., Applications to . . . • if we divide our investment amount between different This Idea Also Works! independent financial instruments, References to a . . . • then we can drastically decrease the corresponding risk. Reference to a Neural . . . Home Page Title Page ◭◭ ◮◮ ◭ ◮ Page 6 of 32 Go Back Full Screen Close Quit

  7. The Main Idea Behind . . . Example 6. A Similar Idea Works Well in Measurement A Similar Idea Works . . . • Suppose that we have n results x 1 , . . . , x n of measuring How Markowitz . . . the same quantity x . What If Side Effects . . . Applications to . . . • Suppose that the measurement error x i − x has mean This Idea Also Works! 0 and standard deviation σ i . References to a . . . • Suppose that measurement errors corresponding to dif- Reference to a Neural . . . ferent measurements are independent. Home Page • Then we can decrease the estimation error if, Title Page – instead of the original estimates x i for x , ◭◭ ◮◮ � n – we use their weighted average � x = w i · x i , for ◭ ◮ i =1 � n Page 7 of 32 some weights w i ≥ 0 for which w i = 1 . i =1 Go Back • In this case, the standard deviation of the estimate � x � n Full Screen is equal to σ 2 = w 2 i · σ 2 i . Close i =1 Quit

  8. The Main Idea Behind . . . Example 7. Measurement (cont-d) A Similar Idea Works . . . • We want to find the weights w i that minimize σ 2 under How Markowitz . . . � n What If Side Effects . . . the given constraint w i = 1. i =1 Applications to . . . • By using the Lagrange multiplier method, we get the This Idea Also Works! following unconstrained optimization problem: References to a . . . � n � n � � Reference to a Neural . . . w 2 i · σ 2 i + λ · w i − 1 → min . Home Page i i =1 i =1 Title Page • Differentiating with respect to w i and equating the ◭◭ ◮◮ derivative to 0, we get = − λ ◭ ◮ def 2 w i · σ 2 i + λ = 0 , so w i = c · σ − 1 i , where c 2 . Page 8 of 32 • This constant c can be found from the condition that Go Back σ − 2 � n 1 i w i = 1: we get c = ; thus, w i = . � � n n Full Screen i =1 σ − 2 σ − 2 j j j =1 j =1 Close Quit

  9. The Main Idea Behind . . . Example 8. Measurement (final) A Similar Idea Works . . . � n 1 • For these weights, σ 2 = How Markowitz . . . w 2 i · σ 2 i = . � n What If Side Effects . . . σ − 2 i =1 j Applications to . . . j =1 � n This Idea Also Works! σ − 2 is larger than each of its terms σ − 2 • The sum j . j References to a . . . j =1 Reference to a Neural . . . • Thus, the inverse σ 2 of this sum is smaller than each Home Page of the inverses σ 2 j . Title Page • So, combining measurement results indeed decreases ◭◭ ◮◮ the approximation error. ◭ ◮ • In particular, when all measurements are equally accu- rate, i.e., when σ 1 = . . . = σ n , we get σ = σ Page 9 of 32 √ n. Go Back Full Screen Close Quit

  10. The Main Idea Behind . . . Example 9. Optimal Portfolio When Different Instruments A Similar Idea Works . . . Are Independent How Markowitz . . . • So far, we considered the case when different financial What If Side Effects . . . instruments are independent and identical. Applications to . . . This Idea Also Works! • Let us now consider a more general case, when we still References to a . . . assume that: Reference to a Neural . . . – the financial instruments are independent, but Home Page – we take into account that these instrument may Title Page have individual values µ i and σ i . ◭◭ ◮◮ • In this case, the first portfolio optimization problem ◭ ◮ takes the following form: Page 10 of 32 � n w 2 i · σ 2 – minimize i Go Back i =1 � � n n Full Screen – under the constraints w i · µ i = µ and w i = 1 . i =1 i =1 Close Quit

  11. The Main Idea Behind . . . Example 10. When Different Are Independent (cont-d) A Similar Idea Works . . . • Lagrange multiplier methods leads to: How Markowitz . . . � n � � n � What If Side Effects . . . � n � � w 2 i · σ 2 + λ ′ · i + λ · w i · µ i − µ w i − 1 → min . Applications to . . . i =1 i =1 i =1 This Idea Also Works! • Differentiating this expression with respect to w i and References to a . . . equating the derivative to 0, we conclude that Reference to a Neural . . . i + λ · µ i + λ ′ = 0 , i.e., w i = a · ( µ i · σ − 2 2 w i · σ 2 i ) + b · σ − 2 i , Home Page = − λ ′ = − λ Title Page def def where a 2 and b 2 . ◭◭ ◮◮ � n • For these w i , w i · µ i = µ and w i = 1 are: ◭ ◮ i =1 n Page 11 of 32 � def ( µ i ) k · σ − 2 a · Σ 2 + b · Σ 1 = µ, a · Σ 1 + b · Σ 0 = 1 , where Σ k = i . Go Back i =1 Full Screen • Thus, a = Σ 1 − µ · Σ 0 and b = µ · Σ 1 − Σ 2 . Σ 2 Σ 2 1 − Σ 0 · Σ 2 1 − Σ 0 · Σ 2 Close Quit

Download Presentation
Download Policy: The content available on the website is offered to you 'AS IS' for your personal information and use only. It cannot be commercialized, licensed, or distributed on other websites without prior consent from the author. To download a presentation, simply click this link. If you encounter any difficulties during the download process, it's possible that the publisher has removed the file from their server.

Recommend


More recommend