ec487 advanced microeconomics part i lecture 4
play

EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 4 Leonardo Felli - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 4 Leonardo Felli 32L.LG.04 20 October, 2017 Marshallian Demands as Correspondences We consider now the case in which consumers preferences are strictly monotonic and weakly convex . In this


  1. EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 4 Leonardo Felli 32L.LG.04 20 October, 2017

  2. Marshallian Demands as Correspondences We consider now the case in which consumers’ preferences are strictly monotonic and weakly convex . In this case Marshallian demands may be correspondence . Assume they are. Definition A correspondence is defined as a mapping F : X ⇒ Y such that F ( x ) ⊂ Y for all x ∈ X . Definition The graph of a correspondence F : X ⇒ Y is the set: G ( F ) = { ( x , y ) ∈ X × Y | y ∈ F ( x ) } Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 20 October, 2017 2 / 45

  3. Fixed Point Theorem Definition A fixed point for a correspondence F : X ⇒ Y is a vector x ∗ such that x ∗ ∈ F ( x ∗ ) Theorem (Kakutani’s Fixed Point Theorem) Let X be a compact, convex and non-empty set in R N . Let F : X ⇒ X be a correspondence. Assume that G ( F ) is closed and that F ( x ) is convex for every x ∈ X then F has a fixed point. Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 20 October, 2017 3 / 45

  4. Kakutani’s Fixed Point Theorem Here is an alternative statement of Kakutani’s Fixed Point Theorem (equivalent). Theorem (Kakutani’s Fixed Point Theorem) Let X be a compact, convex and non-empty set in R N . Let F : X ⇒ X be a correspondence such that: ◮ F is non-empty; ◮ F is convex valued; ◮ F is upper-hemi-continuous. Then there exists a vector x ∗ ∈ X such that: x ∗ ∈ F ( x ∗ ) Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 20 October, 2017 4 / 45

  5. Upper-hemi-continuity Definition A correspondence F : X ⇒ Y where X and Y are compact, convex subsets of Euclidean space is upper-hemi-continuous if and only if given the two converging sequences { x n } ⊂ X and { y n } ⊂ Y such that: { x n } ∞ { y n } ∞ n =1 → x ∈ X ; n =1 → y ∈ Y and: y n ∈ F ( x n ) ∀ n it is the case that y ∈ F ( x ) . Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 20 October, 2017 5 / 45

  6. Upper-hemi-continuity (cont’d) Notice that Result Upper-hemi-continuity of the correspondence F ( · ) is equivalent to F ( · ) having a closed graph only if Y is a compact set. Notice that if we consider a degenerate correspondence y = F ( x ) upper-hemi-continuity of F ( x ) is equivalent to continuity of this function and implies that its graph is closed. However, a closed graph does not imply that the function is continuous: example of a discontinuous function with a closed graph is: � 1 if x � = 0 F ( x ) = x 3 if x = 0 Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 20 October, 2017 6 / 45

  7. Existence of Walrasian Equilibrium Theorem (Existence Theorem of Walrasian Equilibrium) Let the excess demand function Z ( p ) be such that: 1. Z ( p ) is upper-hemi-continuous; 2. Z ( p ) is convex-valued; 3. Z ( p ) is bounded; 4. Z ( p ) homogeneous of degree 0 ; 5. Z ( p ) satisfies Walras Law: p Z ( p ) = 0 ; then there exist a vector of prices p ∗ and an induced allocation x ∗ such that: Z ( p ∗ ) ≤ 0 . Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 20 October, 2017 7 / 45

  8. Existence of Walrasian Equilibrium (cont’d) Proof: Once again we shall start from a normalization of prices: p ∈ ∆ L . In this way the excess demand function will be such that: Z : ∆ L ⇒ R L We then consider the following correspondence: p ⇒ Z ( p ) ⇒ p ′ Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 20 October, 2017 8 / 45

  9. Existence of Walrasian Equilibrium (cont’d) Where we define p ′ so that p ′ Z ( p ) is maximized. In other words, denote Z a vector in R L and m ( Z ) the following set of price vectors ˆ p : m ( Z ) = arg max p Z ˆ ˆ (1) p p ∈ ∆ L s.t. ˆ Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 20 October, 2017 9 / 45

  10. Existence of Walrasian Equilibrium (cont’d) Claim The set m ( Z ) is convex. Proof: Consider p ∈ ∆ L and p ′ ∈ ∆ L that solves (1). Then necessarily: p Z = p ′ Z and for every λ ∈ [0 , 1]: [ λ p + (1 − λ ) p ′ ] Z = p Z = p ′ Z . Therefore: [ λ p + (1 − λ ) p ′ ] ∈ m ( Z ) Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 20 October, 2017 10 / 45

  11. Existence of Walrasian Equilibrium (cont’d) Claim The set m ( Z ) is upper-hemi-continuous. In other words, consider the following two sequences: { Z n } → Z ∗ and { p n } → p ∗ such that p n ∈ m ( Z n ) ∀ n then p ∗ ∈ m ( Z ∗ ) . Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 20 October, 2017 11 / 45

  12. Existence of Walrasian Equilibrium (cont’d) Proof: Suppose this is not true then p ∗ �∈ m ( Z ∗ ) p � = p ∗ such that in other words there exists ¯ p Z ∗ > p ∗ Z ∗ ¯ (2) Since { Z n } → Z ∗ and { p n } → p ∗ we get that: p Z n → ¯ p Z ∗ ¯ and p n Z n → p ∗ Z ∗ Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 20 October, 2017 12 / 45

  13. Existence of Walrasian Equilibrium (cont’d) Choose now n large enough or such that: p Z n − ¯ p Z ∗ | | ¯ < ( ε/ 2) (3) | p n Z n − p ∗ Z ∗ | < ( ε/ 2) Conditions (2) and (3) imply p Z n > p ∗ Z ∗ + ε p ∗ Z ∗ + ε 2 > p n Z n ¯ and 2 so that p Z n > p n Z n ¯ a contradiction of the assumption: p n ∈ m ( Z n ). Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 20 October, 2017 13 / 45

  14. Existence of Walrasian Equilibrium (cont’d) Let g : ∆ L ⇒ ∆ L be defined as: g ( p ) = m ( Z ( p )) . Result The composition of two upper-hemi continuous and convex-valued correspondences is itself upper-hemi-continuous and convex-valued. Therefore if Z ( p ) and m ( Z ) are upper-hemi-continuous and convex-valued then g ( p ) = m ( Z ( p )) is upper-hemi-continuous and convex-valued. Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 20 October, 2017 14 / 45

  15. Existence of Walrasian Equilibrium (cont’d) By Kakutani’s Fixed Point Theorem there exists p ∗ such that p ∗ ∈ g ( p ∗ ) . We still need to check that this price vector p ∗ is indeed a Walrasian equilibrium price vector. By definition of g ( p ) and the fact that p ∗ ∈ g ( p ∗ ) we know that p ∗ ∈ arg max p Z ( p ∗ ) p Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 20 October, 2017 15 / 45

  16. Existence of Walrasian Equilibrium (cont’d) In other words p ∗ Z ( p ∗ ) ≥ p Z ( p ∗ ) ∀ p ∈ ∆ L . (4) By Walras Law we know that: p ∗ Z ( p ∗ ) = 0 From (4) we can then prove the following. Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 20 October, 2017 16 / 45

  17. Existence of Walrasian Equilibrium (cont’d) Result The price vector p ∗ is such that: Z ( p ∗ ) ≤ 0 Proof: Assume by way of contradiction that there exists an ℓ ≤ L such that Z ℓ ( p ∗ ) > 0. Choose then ˆ p = (0 , . . . , 0 , 1 , 0 , . . . , 0) where the digit 1 is in the ℓ -th position. p ∈ ∆ L and: We then obtain that ˆ p Z ( p ∗ ) > 0 = p ∗ Z ( p ∗ ) ˆ which contradicts (4). Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 20 October, 2017 17 / 45

  18. Existence of Walrasian Equilibrium (cont’d) Therefore, we have proved that: ◮ there exists a vector of prices p ∗ such that Z ( p ∗ ) ≤ 0 ◮ or that p ∗ is a Walrasian equilibrium price vector. Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 20 October, 2017 18 / 45

  19. Properties of Walrasian Equilibrium: Definitions Recall that x = { x 1 , . . . , x I } denotes an allocation. Definition An allocation x Pareto dominates an alternative allocation ¯ x if and only if: u i ( x i ) ≥ u i (¯ x i ) ∀ i ∈ { 1 , . . . , I } and for some i : u i ( x i ) > u i (¯ x i ) . Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 20 October, 2017 19 / 45

  20. Properties of Walrasian Equilibrium: Definitions (cont’d) In other words, the allocation x makes no one worse-off and someone strictly better-off. Definition An allocation x is feasible in a pure exchange economy if and only if: I � x i ℓ ≤ ¯ ω ℓ ∀ ℓ ∈ { 1 , . . . , L } . i =1 Definition An allocation x is Pareto efficient if and only if it is feasible and there does not exist an other feasible allocation that Pareto-dominates x . Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 20 October, 2017 20 / 45

  21. Properties of Walrasian Equilibrium: Definitions (cont’d) x 2 ✛ ✻ 2 x 1 1 x p x q q ¯ x q x 2 1 ✲ ❄ x 1 2 Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 20 October, 2017 21 / 45

  22. Benevolent Central Planner A standard way to identify a Pareto-efficient allocation is to introduce a benevolent central planner that has the authority to re-allocate resources across consumers so as to exhaust any gains-from-trade available. Result An allocation x ∗ is Pareto-efficient if and only if there exists a vector of weights λ = ( λ 1 , . . . , λ I ) , λ i ≥ 0 , for all i = 1 , . . . , I and λ h > 0 for at least one h ≤ I, such that x ∗ solves the following problem: I λ i u i ( x i ) � max x 1 ,..., x I i =1 (5) I x i ≤ ¯ � s.t ω i =1 Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 20 October, 2017 22 / 45

Download Presentation
Download Policy: The content available on the website is offered to you 'AS IS' for your personal information and use only. It cannot be commercialized, licensed, or distributed on other websites without prior consent from the author. To download a presentation, simply click this link. If you encounter any difficulties during the download process, it's possible that the publisher has removed the file from their server.

Recommend


More recommend