ec487 advanced microeconomics part i lecture 5
play

EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5 Leonardo Felli - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5 Leonardo Felli 32L.LG.04 27 October, 2017 Pareto Efficient Allocation Recall the following result: Result An allocation x is Pareto-efficient if and only if there exists a vector of weights


  1. EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5 Leonardo Felli 32L.LG.04 27 October, 2017

  2. Pareto Efficient Allocation Recall the following result: Result An allocation x ∗ is Pareto-efficient if and only if there exists a vector of weights λ = ( λ 1 , . . . , λ I ) , λ i ≥ 0 , for all i ≤ I and λ h > 0 for at least one h ≤ I, such that x ∗ solves the following problem: I λ i u i ( x i ) � max x 1 ,..., x I i =1 (1) I x i ≤ ¯ � s.t ω i =1 Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 27 October, 2017 2 / 53

  3. Pareto Efficient Allocation (cont’d) Recall we proved the only if statement. Proof: If: If x ∗ is Pareto-efficient then there exist λ such that x ∗ solves (2). To prove this implication we need the Second Welfare Theorem and the following Result. Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 27 October, 2017 3 / 53

  4. Pareto Efficient Allocation (cont’d) Result Let U : R L + → R be continuously differentiable, concave and monotonic. Consider the following problem: max U ( x ) s.t. p x ≤ p ω x ∈ R N + Then there exists a µ > 0 such that ∂ U ( x ) = µ p ℓ ∀ ℓ = 1 , . . . , L ∂ x ℓ Proof: By Kuhn-Tucker Theorem. Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 27 October, 2017 4 / 53

  5. Pareto Efficient Allocation (cont’d) We can now re-state the if statement above as follows. Result ( If:) Assume that x ∗ is a Pareto-efficient allocation with x ∗ , i > 0 for all i ≤ I, and that u i ( · ) are monotonic, concave and continuously differentiable. Then there exists an I-tuple λ 1 , . . . , λ I > 0 such that x ∗ solves the planner’s problem (2). Moreover, λ i is the inverse of the marginal utility of income. Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 27 October, 2017 5 / 53

  6. Pareto Efficient Allocation (cont’d) Proof: By Second Welfare Theorem, since x ∗ is Pareto-efficient it is a Walrasian Equilibrium for endowments x ∗ , i = ω i and a price vector p ∗ > 0. Therefore for a given p ∗ consumers maximize their utility subject to budget constraint by choosing x ∗ , i . In other words, by the result above, there exists a I -tuple: γ 1 , . . . , γ I > 0 such that: ∂ u i ( x ∗ , i ) = γ i p ∗ ∀ i , ∀ ℓ ℓ ∂ x i ℓ Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 27 October, 2017 6 / 53

  7. Pareto Efficient Allocation (cont’d) Consider now the central planner’s Problem: I λ i u i ( x i ) � max x 1 ,..., x I i =1 (2) I x i ≤ ¯ � s.t ω i =1 It is a concave problem: concave objective function and linear constraint, therefore x ∗ solves it if we can find an L -tuple α 1 , . . . , α L > 0 such that: � I � λ i u i ( x ∗ , i ) � ∂ i =1 = α ℓ ∀ i , ∀ ℓ ∂ x i ℓ Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 27 October, 2017 7 / 53

  8. Pareto Efficient Allocation (cont’d) or λ i ∂ u i ( x ∗ , i ) = α ℓ ∀ i , ∀ ℓ ∂ x i ℓ Choosing now λ i = 1 α ℓ = p ∗ ℓ γ i and noticing that γ i is the marginal utility of income concludes the proof. Notice that α ℓ are the shadow prices of the feasibility conditions , and according to the result above correspond to the Walrasian equilibrium prices. Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 27 October, 2017 8 / 53

  9. Production Economy Consider now an economy with I consumers and J producers characterized by their production possibility set Y j . Define a production economy with private ownership as follows: � � ( ω 1 , . . . , ω I ); u i ( · ); Y j ; θ j E = i , ∀ i ≤ I , ∀ j ≤ J where θ j i is the share owned by consumer i of firm j , of course: I � θ j i = 1 ∀ j ≤ J i =1 Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 27 October, 2017 9 / 53

  10. Walrasian Equilibrium with Production: Definition Define a Walrasian equilibrium for a production economy E as: � � p ∗ ; ( x ∗ , 1 , . . . , x ∗ , I ); ( y ∗ , 1 , . . . , y ∗ , J ) such that: x ∗ , i solves for every i ≤ I : J p ∗ x i ≤ p ∗ ω i + � θ j p ∗ y ∗ , j � u i ( x i ) � max s.t. i x i j =1 Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 27 October, 2017 10 / 53

  11. Walrasian Equilibrium with Production: Definition (cont’d) y ∗ , j solves for every j ≤ J : y j ∈ Y j y j p ∗ y j max s.t. and market clearing conditions are satisfied: I J I x ∗ , i − y ∗ , j − ω j ≤ 0 � � � i =1 j =1 i =1 Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 27 October, 2017 11 / 53

  12. Aggregate Excess Demand Define aggregate excess demand for this economy as: I J I � � � x i ( p ) − y j ( p ) − ω i Z ( p ) = i =1 j =1 i =1 where x i ( p ) is consumer i ’s Marshallian demand and y j ( p ) is firm j ’s net supply: y j ℓ ( p ) > 0 is the supply of commodity ℓ while y j κ ( p ) < 0 is minus unconditional factor demand of commodity κ . Notice that Z ( p ) is homogeneous of degree zero in p . Both x i ( p ) and y j ( p ) are homogeneous of degree zero in p . Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 27 October, 2017 12 / 53

  13. Walras Law Walras Law: p Z ( p ) = 0 . This is obtained once again by summing each consumer’s budget constraint: J p x i ( p ) − p ω i − � θ j p y j ( p ) � � = 0 i j =1 That is: I I I J p ω i − � � � � θ j p x i ( p ) − � p y j ( p ) � = 0 i i =1 i =1 i =1 j =1 Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 27 October, 2017 13 / 53

  14. Walras Law (cont’d) In other words: � I I I J � p ω i − � � � � p x i ( p ) − θ j p y j ( p ) � � = 0 i i =1 i =1 j =1 i =1 or   I I J ω i − � � � x i ( p ) − y j ( p )  = 0 p  i =1 i =1 j =1 We can now state the three main Theorems we have proved in a pure exchange economy for the production economy E . Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 27 October, 2017 14 / 53

  15. Existence Theorem Theorem (Existence Theorem) Consider a Z ( p ) that satisfies the following conditions: 1. Z ( p ) is non-empty; 2. Z ( p ) is convex valued; 3. Z ( p ) is upper-hemi-continuous; 4. Z ( p ) is homogeneous of degree 0; 5. Z ( p ) satisfies Walras Law; 6. Z ( p ) is bounded; then there exists p ∗ such that Z ( p ∗ ) ≤ 0 . Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 27 October, 2017 15 / 53

  16. Properties of Walrasian Equilibrium We now move to the properties of Walrasian equilibrium in the production economy E . Definition An allocation is feasible for a production economy E if and only if there exists a production plan y j for every firm j ≤ J such that y j ∈ Y j ∀ j ≤ J and I I J x i ≤ ω i + � � � y j i =1 i =1 j =1 Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 27 October, 2017 16 / 53

  17. Properties of Walrasian Equilibrium (cont’d) Definition An allocation is Pareto-efficient for a production economy E if and only if ◮ it is feasible ◮ and there does not exists an alternative feasible allocation ˆ x that Pareto-dominates it . Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 27 October, 2017 17 / 53

  18. First Welfare Theorem Theorem (First Fundamental Theorem of Welfare Economics) Let E be a production economy with consumer preferences satisfying weak monotonicity. p ∗ ; ( x ∗ , 1 , . . . , x ∗ , I ); ( y ∗ , 1 , . . . , y ∗ , J ) � � Let be a Walrasian equilibrium for E . Then x ∗ is a Pareto-efficient allocation. Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 27 October, 2017 18 / 53

  19. Second Welfare Theorem Theorem (Second Welfare Theorem) Assume that x ∗ , such that x ∗ , i > 0 , is Pareto-efficient and that ◮ preferences u i ( · ) are strongly monotonic; ◮ preferences are convex: u i ( · ) are quasi-concave; ◮ technology Y j is convex for every j ≤ J and 0 ∈ Y j . ω i for i ≤ I and Then there exists a redistribution of endowments ¯ a vector of shares ¯ θ j i , for i ≤ I and j ≤ J such that � � p ∗ ; ( x ∗ , 1 , . . . , x ∗ , I ); ( y ∗ , 1 , . . . , y ∗ , J ) is a Walrasian equilibrium for the economy ¯ E . Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 27 October, 2017 19 / 53

  20. Second Welfare Theorem: Lemma Lemma Assume that x ∗ , such that x ∗ , i > 0 , is Pareto-efficient and that: ◮ preferences are strongly monotonic; ◮ preferences are convex; ◮ Y j are convex for every j ≤ J; ◮ 0 ∈ Y j for every j ≤ J. Then there exists a y ∗ , j for every firm j ≤ J and a vector p ∗ such that: I J I x ∗ , i = y ∗ , j + � � � ω i ; a) i =1 j =1 i =1 b) u i ( x ′ i ) > u i ( x ∗ , i ) implies p ∗ x ′ i > p ∗ x ∗ , i ; c) p ∗ y ∗ , j ≥ p ∗ y j for every y j ∈ Y j and every j ≤ J. Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 27 October, 2017 20 / 53

  21. Second Welfare Theorem: Proof Proof: Given this Lemma we just need to find the re-distribution i , ∀ i , which at p ∗ gives exactly ω i , ¯ θ j � p ∗ x ∗ , i � ¯ to every consumer. I Let V ∗ = p ∗ x ∗ , i and � i =1 V ∗ i = p ∗ x ∗ , i . Let also s i = V ∗ i V ∗ be i ’s share of the total value. Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 27 October, 2017 21 / 53

Download Presentation
Download Policy: The content available on the website is offered to you 'AS IS' for your personal information and use only. It cannot be commercialized, licensed, or distributed on other websites without prior consent from the author. To download a presentation, simply click this link. If you encounter any difficulties during the download process, it's possible that the publisher has removed the file from their server.

Recommend


More recommend