unconstrained optimization
play

Unconstrained Optimization -4 0 -4 -2 -2 BEEM103 Mathematics - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

Constrained Optimization Constrained Optimization An Example An Example Utility maximization Utility maximization Summary Summary Unconstrained Optimization -4 0 -4 -2 -2 BEEM103 Mathematics for Economists 0 0 2 2 4 4 y x


  1. Constrained Optimization Constrained Optimization An Example An Example Utility maximization Utility maximization Summary Summary Unconstrained Optimization -4 0 -4 -2 -2 BEEM103 Mathematics for Economists 0 0 2 2 4 4 y x Constrained Optimization 1 -10 -20 Dieter Balkenborg z Department of Economics, University of Exeter -30 Department of Economics, University of Exeter -40 Week 3 -50 Balkenborg Constrained Optimization 1 Balkenborg Constrained Optimization 1 Constrained Optimization Constrained Optimization An Example An Example Utility maximization Utility maximization Summary Summary Constrained Optimization: Constrained Optimization y ≥ 1 Examples: -4 -4 -2 0 A consumer maximizes his utility subject to his budget -2 1 0 0 2 2 constraint. 4 4 y x -10 A producer minimizes costs subject to the constraint that a 2 certain amount is produced. -20 Moral hazard: An insurer tries to select an insurance contract z 3 -30 that maximizes profits subject to the constraints that it is valuable to the consumer (“Participation Constraint”) and -40 that the consumer has an incentive to be careful (“Incentive Constraint”). Basic result: Full insurance is not optimal -50 because it would make consumer act careless. Balkenborg Constrained Optimization 1 Balkenborg Constrained Optimization 1

  2. Constrained Optimization Constrained Optimization An Example An Example Utility maximization Utility maximization Summary Summary Constrained Optimization Problem The constraints carve out a region of the plane. Objective: Find the (absolute) maximum of the function g 1 (x,y)=0 z = f ( x , y ) subject to the inequality constraints g 5 (x,y)=0 Region where all constraints g 5 (x,y)<0 g 1 ( x , y ) ≥ 0 satisfied g 2 ( x , y ) ≥ 0 g 5 (x,y)>0 . . . g K ( x , y ) ≥ 0 g 1 (x,y)>0 g 1 (x,y)<0 g 2 (x,y)=0 Thus find pair ( x ∗ , y ∗ ) satisfying the constraints such that we have for all g 2 (x,y)>0 other pairs ( x , y ) satisfying the constraints: f ( x ∗ , y ∗ ) ≥ f ( x , y ) . f ( x , y ) is called the “objective function” and I call g 2 (x,y)<0 g 1 ( x , y ) , . . . , g K ( x , y ) the “constraining functions” of the problem. Balkenborg Constrained Optimization 1 Balkenborg Constrained Optimization 1 Constrained Optimization Constrained Optimization An Example An Example Utility maximization Utility maximization Summary Summary Example 1: Consumer Optimization Example 2: Cost Minimization A consumer wants to maximize his utility 1 1 2 in a u ( x , y ) = ( x + 1 ) ( y + 1 ) A producer with production function Q ( K , L ) = K 6 L perfectly competitive market wants to minimize costs subject to subject to his budget constraint producing at least Q 0 units. b − p x x − p y y ≥ 0 Maximize − ( rK + wL ) and the non-negativity constraints x ≥ 0 y ≥ 0 subject to Q ( K , L ) − Q 0 ≥ 0 3 y ≥ K 0 2 ≥ 0 1 L 0 0 1 2 3 x Balkenborg Constrained Optimization 1 Balkenborg Constrained Optimization 1

  3. Constrained Optimization Constrained Optimization An Example An Example Utility maximization Utility maximization Summary Summary Example 3: Shortest Route The Island A swimmer who is currently at the coordinates ( a , b ) wants to swim along the shortest route to the square island with corner x+1=0 1-x=0 3 points ( − 1 , 1 ) , ( 1 , − 1 ) , ( − 1 , 1 ) , ( 1 , 1 ) . Instead of minimizing the distance we can maximize the negative 2 of the square of the distance y − ( x − a ) 2 − ( y − b ) 2 1-y=0 1 subject to the constraints x + 1 ≥ 0 0 -3 -2 -1 1 2 3 x 1 − x ≥ 0 y+1=0 -1 y + 1 ≥ 0 1 − y ≥ 0 -2 ( x , y ) is a point in the square carved out by the solutions to the -3 four inequalities. Balkenborg Constrained Optimization 1 Balkenborg Constrained Optimization 1 Constrained Optimization Constrained Optimization An Example An Example Utility maximization Utility maximization Summary Summary The Swimmer Binding constraints A constraint is binding at the optimum if it holds with equality in x+1=0 1-x=0 the optimum. In the above picture only one of the four the 3 constraints is binding. All non-binding constraints can be ignored. If they are left out the optimum does not change. 2 y x+1=0 1-x=0 3 1-y=0 1 2 (a,b) y 0 -3 -2 -1 1 2 3 1-y=0 x 1 y+1=0 -1 (a,b) 0 -3 -2 -1 1 2 3 x y+1=0 -2 -1 -2 -3 Balkenborg Constrained Optimization 1 Balkenborg -3 Constrained Optimization 1

  4. Constrained Optimization Constrained Optimization An Example An Example Utility maximization Utility maximization Summary Summary The Lagrangian Approach The Lagrangian Approach The Lagrangian approach transfers a constrained optimization problem into an unconstrained optimization problem and 1 a pricing problem. 2 The Lagrangian: The new function to be optimized is called the Lagrangian. For L ( x , y ) = f ( x , y ) + λ 1 g 1 ( x , y ) + λ 2 g 2 ( x , y ) + · · · + λ K g K ( x , y ) each constraint a shadow price is introduced, called a Lagrange multiplier. In the new unconstrained optimization problem a constraint can be violated, but only at a cost. The pricing problem is to find shadow prices for the constraints such that the solutions to the new and the original optimization problem are identical. Balkenborg Constrained Optimization 1 Balkenborg Constrained Optimization 1 Constrained Optimization Constrained Optimization An Example An Example Utility maximization Utility maximization Summary Summary Theorem Suppose we are given numbers λ 1 , λ 2 , . . . , λ K ≥ 0 and a pair of The Lagrangian: numbers ( x ∗ , y ∗ ) such that L ( x , y ) = f ( x , y ) + λ 1 g 1 ( x , y ) + λ 2 g 2 ( x , y ) + · · · + λ K g K ( x , y ) λ 1 , λ 2 , . . . , λ K ≥ 0 , i.e. Lagrange mutlipliers are non-negative, 1 2 ( x ∗ , y ∗ ) satisfies all the constraints, i.e., g k ( x ∗ , y ∗ ) ≥ 0 for all 1 ≤ k ≤ K . Proof. 3 ( x ∗ , y ∗ ) is an unconstrained maximum of the Lagrangian Because of the complementarity conditions we have L ( x ∗ , y ∗ ) = f ( x ∗ , y ∗ ) . We have L ( x , y ) ≤ L ( x ∗ , y ∗ ) for any L ( x , y ) . ( x , y ) . If ( x , y ) satisfies all constraints then λ k g k ( x , y ) ≥ 0 for The complementarity conditions 4 each constraint since the λ k are non-negative. Hence λ k g k ( x ∗ , y ∗ ) = 0 f ( x , y ) ≤ L ( x , y ) and therefore f ( x , y ) ≤ f ( x ∗ , y ∗ ) for any point ( x , y ) satisfying the constraints. are satisfied, i.e., either the k-Lagrange multiplier is zero or the k-th constraint binds for 1 ≤ k ≤ K. Then ( x ∗ , y ∗ ) is a maximum for the constrained maximization problem. Balkenborg Constrained Optimization 1 Balkenborg Constrained Optimization 1

  5. Constrained Optimization Constrained Optimization An Example An Example Utility maximization Utility maximization Summary Summary The Method The Swimmer’s Problem Make an informed guess about which constraints are binding 1 at the optimum. (Suppose there are k ∗ such constraints.) The Lagrangian is Set the Lagrange multipliers for all other constraints zero, i.e. 2 − ( x − a ) 2 − ( y − b ) 2 L ( x , y ) = ignore these constraints. + λ 1 ( x + 1 ) + λ 2 ( 1 − x ) + λ 3 ( y + 1 ) + λ 4 ( 1 − y ) Solve the two first -order conditions ∂ L ∂ x = 0, ∂ L ∂ y = 0 together 3 with the conditions that the k ∗ constraints are binding. FOC: (Notice that we have 2 + k ∗ constraints and equations, namely x , y and k ∗ Lagrange multipliers.) ∂ L = − 2 ( x − a ) + λ 1 − λ 2 = 0 ∂ x Check whether the solution is indeed an unconstrained 4 ∂ L optimum of the Lagrangian. (May be difficult.) = − 2 ( y − b ) + λ 3 − λ 4 = 0 ∂ y Check that the Lagrange multipliers are all non-negative and 5 that the solution ( x ∗ , y ∗ ) satisfies all constraints. If 4. and 5. are violated, start again at 1. with a new guess. 6 Balkenborg Constrained Optimization 1 Balkenborg Constrained Optimization 1 Constrained Optimization Constrained Optimization An Example An Example Utility maximization Utility maximization Summary Summary Case 1: Case 1 x+1=0 1-x=0 Suppose − 1 < x ∗ < 1 , − 1 < y ∗ < 1 . 3 None of the four constraints is “binding” In this case the optimum has to be a stationary point of the 2 objective function. This gives the conditions y 1-y=0 1 ∂ f = − 2 ( x − a ) = 0 ∂ x ∂ f 0 -3 -2 -1 1 2 3 = − 2 ( y − b ) = 0 x ∂ y y+1=0 -1 UNIQUE SOLUTION: ( x ∗ , y ∗ ) = ( a , b ) . Must have: − 1 ≤ a , b ≤ 1 for this to be the optimum. -2 -3 Balkenborg Constrained Optimization 1 Balkenborg Constrained Optimization 1

Download Presentation
Download Policy: The content available on the website is offered to you 'AS IS' for your personal information and use only. It cannot be commercialized, licensed, or distributed on other websites without prior consent from the author. To download a presentation, simply click this link. If you encounter any difficulties during the download process, it's possible that the publisher has removed the file from their server.

Recommend


More recommend