option greeks
play

Option Greeks 1 Introduction Option Greeks 1 Introduction Set-up - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

Option Greeks 1 Introduction Option Greeks 1 Introduction Set-up Assignment: Read Section 12.3 from McDonald. We want to look at the option prices dynamically. Question: What happens with the option price if one of the inputs


  1. Option Greeks 1 Introduction

  2. Option Greeks 1 Introduction

  3. Set-up • Assignment: Read Section 12.3 from McDonald. • We want to look at the option prices dynamically. • Question: What happens with the option price if one of the inputs (parameters) changes? • First, we give names to these effects of perturbations of parameters to the option price. Then, we can see what happens in the contexts of the pricing models we use.

  4. Set-up • Assignment: Read Section 12.3 from McDonald. • We want to look at the option prices dynamically. • Question: What happens with the option price if one of the inputs (parameters) changes? • First, we give names to these effects of perturbations of parameters to the option price. Then, we can see what happens in the contexts of the pricing models we use.

  5. Set-up • Assignment: Read Section 12.3 from McDonald. • We want to look at the option prices dynamically. • Question: What happens with the option price if one of the inputs (parameters) changes? • First, we give names to these effects of perturbations of parameters to the option price. Then, we can see what happens in the contexts of the pricing models we use.

  6. Set-up • Assignment: Read Section 12.3 from McDonald. • We want to look at the option prices dynamically. • Question: What happens with the option price if one of the inputs (parameters) changes? • First, we give names to these effects of perturbations of parameters to the option price. Then, we can see what happens in the contexts of the pricing models we use.

  7. Vocabulary

  8. Notes • Ψ is rarer and denotes the sensitivity to the changes in the dividend yield δ • vega is not a Greek letter - sometimes λ or κ are used instead • The “prescribed” perturbations in the definitions above are problematic . . . • It is more sensible to look at the Greeks as derivatives of option prices (in a given model)! • As usual, we will talk about calls - the puts are analogous

  9. Notes • Ψ is rarer and denotes the sensitivity to the changes in the dividend yield δ • vega is not a Greek letter - sometimes λ or κ are used instead • The “prescribed” perturbations in the definitions above are problematic . . . • It is more sensible to look at the Greeks as derivatives of option prices (in a given model)! • As usual, we will talk about calls - the puts are analogous

  10. Notes • Ψ is rarer and denotes the sensitivity to the changes in the dividend yield δ • vega is not a Greek letter - sometimes λ or κ are used instead • The “prescribed” perturbations in the definitions above are problematic . . . • It is more sensible to look at the Greeks as derivatives of option prices (in a given model)! • As usual, we will talk about calls - the puts are analogous

  11. Notes • Ψ is rarer and denotes the sensitivity to the changes in the dividend yield δ • vega is not a Greek letter - sometimes λ or κ are used instead • The “prescribed” perturbations in the definitions above are problematic . . . • It is more sensible to look at the Greeks as derivatives of option prices (in a given model)! • As usual, we will talk about calls - the puts are analogous

  12. Notes • Ψ is rarer and denotes the sensitivity to the changes in the dividend yield δ • vega is not a Greek letter - sometimes λ or κ are used instead • The “prescribed” perturbations in the definitions above are problematic . . . • It is more sensible to look at the Greeks as derivatives of option prices (in a given model)! • As usual, we will talk about calls - the puts are analogous

  13. The Delta: The binomial model • Recall the replicating portfolio for a call option on a stock S : ∆ shares of stock & B invested in the riskless asset. • So, the price of a call at any time t was C = ∆ S + Be rt with S denoting the price of the stock at time t • Differentiating with respect to S , we get ∂ ∂ S C = ∆ • And, I did tell you that the notation was intentional ...

  14. The Delta: The binomial model • Recall the replicating portfolio for a call option on a stock S : ∆ shares of stock & B invested in the riskless asset. • So, the price of a call at any time t was C = ∆ S + Be rt with S denoting the price of the stock at time t • Differentiating with respect to S , we get ∂ ∂ S C = ∆ • And, I did tell you that the notation was intentional ...

  15. The Delta: The binomial model • Recall the replicating portfolio for a call option on a stock S : ∆ shares of stock & B invested in the riskless asset. • So, the price of a call at any time t was C = ∆ S + Be rt with S denoting the price of the stock at time t • Differentiating with respect to S , we get ∂ ∂ S C = ∆ • And, I did tell you that the notation was intentional ...

  16. The Delta: The binomial model • Recall the replicating portfolio for a call option on a stock S : ∆ shares of stock & B invested in the riskless asset. • So, the price of a call at any time t was C = ∆ S + Be rt with S denoting the price of the stock at time t • Differentiating with respect to S , we get ∂ ∂ S C = ∆ • And, I did tell you that the notation was intentional ...

  17. The Delta: The Black-Scholes formula • The Black-Scholes call option price is C ( S , K , r , T , δ, σ ) = Se − δ T N ( d 1 ) − Ke − rT N ( d 2 ) with √ 1 K ) + ( r − δ + 1 [ln( S 2 σ 2 ) T ] , d 2 = d 1 − σ d 1 = √ T σ T • Calculating the ∆ we get . . . ∂ ∂ S C ( S , . . . ) = e − δ T N ( d 1 ) • This allows us to reinterpret the expression for the Black-Scholes price in analogy with the replicating portfolio from the binomial model

  18. The Delta: The Black-Scholes formula • The Black-Scholes call option price is C ( S , K , r , T , δ, σ ) = Se − δ T N ( d 1 ) − Ke − rT N ( d 2 ) with √ 1 K ) + ( r − δ + 1 [ln( S 2 σ 2 ) T ] , d 2 = d 1 − σ d 1 = √ T σ T • Calculating the ∆ we get . . . ∂ ∂ S C ( S , . . . ) = e − δ T N ( d 1 ) • This allows us to reinterpret the expression for the Black-Scholes price in analogy with the replicating portfolio from the binomial model

  19. The Delta: The Black-Scholes formula • The Black-Scholes call option price is C ( S , K , r , T , δ, σ ) = Se − δ T N ( d 1 ) − Ke − rT N ( d 2 ) with √ 1 K ) + ( r − δ + 1 [ln( S 2 σ 2 ) T ] , d 2 = d 1 − σ d 1 = √ T σ T • Calculating the ∆ we get . . . ∂ ∂ S C ( S , . . . ) = e − δ T N ( d 1 ) • This allows us to reinterpret the expression for the Black-Scholes price in analogy with the replicating portfolio from the binomial model

  20. The Delta: The Black-Scholes formula • The Black-Scholes call option price is C ( S , K , r , T , δ, σ ) = Se − δ T N ( d 1 ) − Ke − rT N ( d 2 ) with √ 1 K ) + ( r − δ + 1 [ln( S 2 σ 2 ) T ] , d 2 = d 1 − σ d 1 = √ T σ T • Calculating the ∆ we get . . . ∂ ∂ S C ( S , . . . ) = e − δ T N ( d 1 ) • This allows us to reinterpret the expression for the Black-Scholes price in analogy with the replicating portfolio from the binomial model

  21. The Gamma • Regardless of the model - due to put-call parity - Γ is the same for European puts and calls (with the same parameters) • In general, one gets Γ as ∂ 2 ∂ S 2 C ( S , . . . ) = . . . • In the Black-Scholes setting ∂ S 2 C ( S , . . . ) = e − δ T − 0 . 5 d 2 ∂ 2 1 √ 2 π T S σ • If Γ of a derivative is positive when evaluated at all prices S , we say that this derivative is convex

  22. The Gamma • Regardless of the model - due to put-call parity - Γ is the same for European puts and calls (with the same parameters) • In general, one gets Γ as ∂ 2 ∂ S 2 C ( S , . . . ) = . . . • In the Black-Scholes setting ∂ S 2 C ( S , . . . ) = e − δ T − 0 . 5 d 2 ∂ 2 1 √ 2 π T S σ • If Γ of a derivative is positive when evaluated at all prices S , we say that this derivative is convex

  23. The Gamma • Regardless of the model - due to put-call parity - Γ is the same for European puts and calls (with the same parameters) • In general, one gets Γ as ∂ 2 ∂ S 2 C ( S , . . . ) = . . . • In the Black-Scholes setting ∂ S 2 C ( S , . . . ) = e − δ T − 0 . 5 d 2 ∂ 2 1 √ 2 π T S σ • If Γ of a derivative is positive when evaluated at all prices S , we say that this derivative is convex

  24. The Gamma • Regardless of the model - due to put-call parity - Γ is the same for European puts and calls (with the same parameters) • In general, one gets Γ as ∂ 2 ∂ S 2 C ( S , . . . ) = . . . • In the Black-Scholes setting ∂ S 2 C ( S , . . . ) = e − δ T − 0 . 5 d 2 ∂ 2 1 √ 2 π T S σ • If Γ of a derivative is positive when evaluated at all prices S , we say that this derivative is convex

  25. The Vega • Heuristically, an increase in volatility of S yields an increase in the price of a call or put option on S • So, since vega is defined as ∂ ∂σ C ( . . . , σ ) we conclude that vega ≥ 0 • What is the expression for vega in the Black-Scholes setting?

  26. The Vega • Heuristically, an increase in volatility of S yields an increase in the price of a call or put option on S • So, since vega is defined as ∂ ∂σ C ( . . . , σ ) we conclude that vega ≥ 0 • What is the expression for vega in the Black-Scholes setting?

Download Presentation
Download Policy: The content available on the website is offered to you 'AS IS' for your personal information and use only. It cannot be commercialized, licensed, or distributed on other websites without prior consent from the author. To download a presentation, simply click this link. If you encounter any difficulties during the download process, it's possible that the publisher has removed the file from their server.

Recommend


More recommend