misallocation or mismeasurement
play

Misallocation or Mismeasurement? Mark Bils, University of Rochester - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

Misallocation or Mismeasurement? Mark Bils, University of Rochester and NBER Pete Klenow, Stanford University and NBER Cian Ruane, Stanford University February 2017 1 / 68 Motivation Large gaps in average revenue products (TFPR) across plants


  1. Misallocation or Mismeasurement? Mark Bils, University of Rochester and NBER Pete Klenow, Stanford University and NBER Cian Ruane, Stanford University February 2017 1 / 68

  2. Motivation Large gaps in average revenue products (TFPR) across plants ◮ Syverson (2011) Huge purported gains from reallocation of inputs ◮ Banerjee & Duflo (2005) ◮ Restuccia & Rogerson (2008) ◮ Hsieh & Klenow (2009, 2014) But big differences in measured average products need not imply big differences in true marginal products 2 / 68

  3. U.S. manufacturing since the 1970s Major increase in TFPR dispersion (Kehrig, 2015) ◮ Implies falling allocative efficiency ◮ If true, lowered TFP growth by about 2.5 percent per year ◮ Cumulated to 55 percent lower TFP by late 2000s ◮ Given measured TFP growth was about 1.7 percent per year, would imply residual TFP growth of 4.2 percent per year Real, or measurement error getting worse? 3 / 68

  4. U.S. Allocative Efficiency & Residual TFP 4 / 68

  5. What we do Propose way to estimate marginal products under: ◮ Measurement error ◮ Misspecification due to overhead costs Apply to: ◮ manufacturing plants in the U.S. 1978–2007 ◮ manufacturing plants in India 1985–2011 Preview of results: ◮ Eliminates the severe decline in U.S. allocative efficiency ◮ Reduces potential gains from reallocation in India by 40% ◮ Leaves U.S. a stable 30% higher allocative efficiency than India 5 / 68

  6. Measurement error in the Indian data Book values instead of market values for capital Number of contract workers not known End-of-previous-year � = beginning-of-current-year stocks Jumps in reported age across years for many plant 6 / 68

  7. Measurement error in the U.S. data Book values instead of market values for capital Census is frequently forced to impute data ◮ SSA, IRS data on a subset of plants, variables ◮ Sometimes impute based on other plants ◮ See White, Reiter and Petrin (2016) for a critique ◮ And Petrin, Rotemberg and White (2017, in progress) 7 / 68

  8. Table of Contents Simple model 1 Full Model 2 Data & Measurement 3 Patterns in the data 4 Test for measurement & specification error 5 Correcting Aggregates 6 8 / 68

  9. Simple model setup �� � 1 �� � 1 − 1 1 − 1 1 ǫ , P = i P 1 − ǫ Y = i Y ǫ 1 − ǫ i i Y i = A i L i max (1 − τ Y i ) P i Y i − wL i ◮ Monopolistic competitor takes w , Y , and P as given � P i Y i ≡ P i Y i + g i � L i ≡ L i + f i 9 / 68

  10. Simple model TFPR P i = markup × marginal cost � � � � ǫ τ i · w 1 P i = × , where τ i ≡ 1 − τ Y ǫ − 1 A i i P i Y i ∝ τ i · L i � � � P i Y i τ i × 1 + g i / ( P i Y i ) TFPR i ≡ ∝ � 1 + f i /L i L i 10 / 68

  11. Numerical example τ i — so the true distortion is fixed over time g i , f i — so additive measurement error is fixed over time A it — so productivity is time-varying � � � PY PY � PY PY L PY L � PY � L L � � L L Firm 1 100 50 2 120 50 2.4 50 25 2 Firm 2 50 50 1 40 50 0.8 25 25 1 11 / 68

  12. Lessons from the numerical example � � P it Y it / � � L it = τ i when constant measurement error, distortions � � � � P it Y it / � � L it on ln ( TFPR ) yields: Regressing ln ◮ 1 if there is no measurement error in TFPR ◮ 0 if all TFPR dispersion is due to measurement error ◮ ∼ 2/3 in the numerical example above Later we generalize in order to: ◮ Allow shocks to measurement error and distortions ◮ Infer the signal from covariance b/w levels, first differences 12 / 68

  13. Projection of First Differences on Levels 13 / 68

  14. Full model vs. Simple model Capital, labor, and intermediates Distortions hitting each input Multiple sectors Shocks to τ and shocks to measurement error Key assumption: measurement error is orthogonal to τ 14 / 68

  15. Table of Contents Simple model 1 Full Model 2 Data & Measurement 3 Patterns in the data 4 Test for measurement & specification error 5 Correcting Aggregates 6 15 / 68

  16. Model (Setup) Closed economy, S sectors, N s firms, L workers, K capital Q = C + X Q = � S s =1 Q θ s s �� N s � 1 1 − 1 1 − 1 ǫ Q s = Q ǫ i si Q si = A si ( K α s si L 1 − α s ) γ s X 1 − γ s si si max R si − (1 + τ L si ) wL si − (1 + τ K si ) rK si − (1 + τ X si ) X si ◮ R si ≡ P si Q si ◮ Monopolistic competitor takes input prices as given 16 / 68

  17. Model (Aggregate TFP) C TFP ≡ L 1 − ˜ α K ˜ α � S s =1 α s γ s θ s ◮ where ˜ α ≡ � S s =1 γ s θ s � S θs � S s =1 γsθs TFP = T × TFP s s =1 ◮ T = reflects sectoral distortions (set aside) Q s ◮ TFP s ≡ ( K α s s L 1 − α s ) γ s X 1 − γ s s s 17 / 68

  18. Model (Sectoral TFP) Suppressing s here and whenever possible: � N � 1 � τ i � 1 − ǫ � ǫ − 1 A ǫ − 1 TFP = i τ i �� � α � γ � � 1 − α � � 1 − γ 1 + τ L 1 + τ K 1 + τ X τ i ≡ i i i �� 1 + τ K � α � γ � 1 + τ L � 1 − α � 1 + τ X � 1 − γ τ ≡ �� N � − 1 where 1 + τ L ≡ R i 1 and so on i =1 R 1+ τ L i 18 / 68

  19. Model (Sectoral TFP Decomposition) 1 TFP = AE · PD · ¯ A · N ǫ − 1 AE ≡ Allocative Efficiency PD ≡ Productivity Dispersion ¯ A ≡ Average productivity 1 ǫ − 1 ≡ Variety N 19 / 68

  20. Model (Sectoral TFP Decomposition) � � � � ǫ − 1 � 1 1 � A i � ǫ − 1 � τ i � A i � 1 − ǫ N N � � ǫ − 1 ǫ − 1 1 1 TFP = × ¯ ˜ N τ N A A i i � �� � � �� � AE = Allocative Efficiency PD s = Productivity Dispersion 1 ¯ × N × A ǫ − 1 � �� � ���� Variety Average Productivity � i ( A i ) ǫ − 1 � 1 � N ˜ 1 ǫ − 1 A = (power mean) N A = � N 1 ¯ i =1 A N (geometric mean) i 20 / 68

  21. Table of Contents Simple model 1 Full Model 2 Data & Measurement 3 Patterns in the data 4 Test for measurement & specification error 5 Correcting Aggregates 6 21 / 68

  22. Indian Annual Survey of Industries (ASI) Survey of Indian Manufacturing Plants ◮ Long panel 1985–2011 ◮ Used in Hsieh and Klenow (2009, 2014) Sampling Frame: ◮ ∼ 43,000 plants per year ◮ All plants > 100 or 200 workers (45% of plant-years) ◮ Probabilistic if > 10 or 20 workers (55% of plant-years) Variables used: ◮ Gross output ( R i ), intermediate inputs ( X i ), labor ( L i ), labor cost ( wL i ), and capital ( K i ) 22 / 68

  23. U.S. Longitudinal Research Database (LRD) U.S. Census Bureau data on manufacturing plants ◮ Long panel, 1978–2007 analyzed so far ◮ Used in Hsieh and Klenow (2009, 2014) Sampling Frame: ◮ Annual Survey of Manufacturing (ASM) plants ◮ ∼ 50k plants with at least one employee ◮ Probabilistic sampling for ∼ 34k plants, certainty for other ∼ 16k Variables used: ◮ Gross output ( R i ), intermediate inputs ( X i ), labor ( L i ), labor cost ( wL i ), and capital ( K i ) 23 / 68

  24. Measurement error in the Indian ASI Frequency Magnitude Age 12.4% 4 years EOY & BOY capital stocks 25.7% 15.4% EOY & BOY goods inventories 22.0% 24.8% EOY & BOY materials inventories 22.3% 20.2% There is measurement error in age if age in year t is not equal to 1 + age in year t − 1 . The magnitude of this measurement error is the median absolute deviation. There is measurement error in stocks and inventories if the deviation of the BOY value in year t from the EOY value in year t − 1 is greater than 1%. The magnitude of this measurement error is the standard deviation of the absolute value of the percentage measurement error. 24 / 68

  25. Data cleaning steps Indian ASI U.S. LRD Step Cleaning Remaining Obs Remaining Obs 1 Starting sample of plant-years 1,159,641 1,767,000 2 Missing no key variables 924,547 1,589,000 3 Common Sector Concordance 899,793 1523,000 4 Trimming extreme TFPR & TFPQ 844,875 1,428,000 The last step trims 1% tails of MRP & TFPQ deviations from sector-year averages 25 / 68

  26. Inferring allocative efficiency from the data � N � 1 − ǫ � 1 � TFPQ i � ǫ − 1 � TFPR i � ǫ − 1 � AE = TFPQ TFPR i � � ǫ � ǫ − 1 R i � A i = TFPQ i = ( � i � ) γ � X 1 − γ L 1 − α K α i i � R i TFPR i = ( � i � ) γ � X 1 − γ L 1 − α K α i i 26 / 68

  27. Inferring allocative efficiency from the data � N � 1 − ǫ � 1 � TFPQ i � ǫ − 1 � TFPR i � ǫ − 1 � AE = TFPQ TFPR i �� N � 1 i TFPQ ǫ − 1 ǫ − 1 TFPQ = i � � � � (1 − α ) γ � � αγ � � 1 − γ ǫ MRP L MRP K MRP X TFPR = ǫ − 1 (1 − α ) γ αγ 1 − γ �� � − 1 � R i 1 ◮ MRPK = and so on � MRPK i R i � ǫ − 1 � � R i ◮ MRPK i = αγ and so on � ǫ K i 27 / 68

  28. Inferring aggregate AE from the data Aggregating within-sector allocative efficiencies: S θst � � S � � s =1 γsθst AE t = AE st s =1 Parameterization: ǫ = 4 based on Redding and Weinstein (2016) α s and γ s inferred from sectoral cost-shares ( r = . 2 ) θ st inferred from sectoral shares of aggregate output 28 / 68

  29. Table of Contents Simple model 1 Full Model 2 Data & Measurement 3 Patterns in the data 4 Test for measurement & specification error 5 Correcting Aggregates 6 29 / 68

Download Presentation
Download Policy: The content available on the website is offered to you 'AS IS' for your personal information and use only. It cannot be commercialized, licensed, or distributed on other websites without prior consent from the author. To download a presentation, simply click this link. If you encounter any difficulties during the download process, it's possible that the publisher has removed the file from their server.

Recommend


More recommend