how to compare different
play

How to Compare Different Localness Property Range Estimations: - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

Need for Data Processing Need to Take . . . Dynamic Case How Preferences Are . . . How to Compare Different Localness Property Range Estimations: Other Common-Sense . . . Main Result A Symmetry-Based How to Compare . . . Auxiliary Result:


  1. Need for Data Processing Need to Take . . . Dynamic Case How Preferences Are . . . How to Compare Different Localness Property Range Estimations: Other Common-Sense . . . Main Result A Symmetry-Based How to Compare . . . Auxiliary Result: How . . . Approach Home Page Title Page Olga Kosheleva and Vladik Kreinovich ◭◭ ◮◮ University of Texas at El Paso ◭ ◮ El Paso, TX 79968, USA olgak@utep.edu, vladik@utep.edu Page 1 of 27 Go Back Full Screen Close Quit

  2. Need for Data Processing Need to Take . . . 1. Outline Dynamic Case • How to compare different range estimators for multi- How Preferences Are . . . variate functions under uncertainty? Localness Property Other Common-Sense . . . • To answer this question, we analyze which utility func- Main Result tions can be used for this task. Specifically, we: How to Compare . . . – introduce various invariance assumptions, Auxiliary Result: How . . . – describe the class of all utility functions which sat- Home Page isfy these assumptions, and Title Page – show how the resulting utility functions can be used ◭◭ ◮◮ to compare different range estimators. ◭ ◮ Page 2 of 27 Go Back Full Screen Close Quit

  3. Need for Data Processing Need to Take . . . 2. Need for Data Processing Dynamic Case • In many practical situations, we are interested: How Preferences Are . . . Localness Property – in the future value of a quantity y Other Common-Sense . . . – or in its current value which is not easy to measure Main Result directly. How to Compare . . . • In such situations: Auxiliary Result: How . . . Home Page – we find easier-to-measure quantities x 1 , . . . , x n which are related to y in a known way y = f ( x 1 , . . . , x n ), Title Page – and we use the measured values � x i of the auxiliary ◭◭ ◮◮ quantities x i to estimate y as � y = f ( � x n ). x 1 , . . . , � ◭ ◮ • This is usually called data processing. Page 3 of 27 Go Back Full Screen Close Quit

  4. Need for Data Processing Need to Take . . . 3. Need to Take Measurement Uncertainty Into Dynamic Case Account How Preferences Are . . . • Measurements are never absolutely accurate. Localness Property Other Common-Sense . . . • Thus, the measured values � x i are somewhat different Main Result from the actual (unknown) values x i . How to Compare . . . • Therefore, the estimate � y = f ( � x n ) is, in general, x 1 , . . . , � Auxiliary Result: How . . . different from the desired value y = f ( x 1 , . . . , x n ). Home Page • Often, the only information that we have about Title Page def ∆ x i = � x i − x i is the upper bound ∆ i : | ∆ x i | ≤ ∆ i . ◭◭ ◮◮ • In this case, the only information that we know about ◭ ◮ each x i is that x i ∈ x i = [ � x i − ∆ i , � x i + ∆ i ]. Page 4 of 27 • We therefore need to find the range y of f ( x 1 , . . . , x n ) Go Back when x i ∈ x i ; this is called interval computations. Full Screen • The exact computation of this range is known to be NP-hard, so we find an enclosure Y ⊇ y . Close Quit

  5. Need for Data Processing Need to Take . . . 4. Dynamic Case Dynamic Case • Often, we are interested in the values y ( t ) correspond- How Preferences Are . . . ing to different t (time, location, etc.). Localness Property Other Common-Sense . . . • Different interval techniques lead to different enclo- Main Result sures Y ( t ), Y ′ ( t ), . . . for y ( t ). How to Compare . . . • How can we compare these results? Auxiliary Result: How . . . Home Page • Of course, if a technique leads to narrower bounds for all t , it is better. Title Page • However, often, one technique is better for some t while ◭◭ ◮◮ another technique is better for other t . ◭ ◮ • In this talk, we propose a symmetry-based approach to Page 5 of 27 comparing two methods. Go Back Full Screen Close Quit

  6. Need for Data Processing Need to Take . . . 5. How Preferences Are Described in Decision The- Dynamic Case ory: The Notion of Utility How Preferences Are . . . • To describe preferences in numerical terms, we select a Localness Property very bad alternative A 0 and a very good one A 1 . Other Common-Sense . . . Main Result • Then, for each p ∈ [0 , 1], we form a lottery L ( p ) in How to Compare . . . which we get A 1 with probability p else A 0 . Auxiliary Result: How . . . • When p ≈ 0, we have L ( p ) < A ; when p ≈ 1, we have Home Page A < L ( p ). Title Page • There exists a threshold value ◭◭ ◮◮ u ( A ) = sup { p : L ( p ) < A } for which: ◭ ◮ – for all p < u ( A ), we have L ( p ) < A , and Page 6 of 27 – for all p > u ( A ), we have L ( p ) > A . Go Back • This threshold value is called the utility of A . Full Screen • Here, A is better than A ′ if and only if u ( A ) > u ( A ′ ). Close Quit

  7. Need for Data Processing Need to Take . . . 6. Application to Our Problem Dynamic Case • The numerical value of the utility depends on the se- How Preferences Are . . . lection of the alternatives A 0 and A 1 . Localness Property Other Common-Sense . . . • One can show that: Main Result – if we select a different pair of alternatives A ′ 0 < A ′ 1 , How to Compare . . . – then the new utility values u ′ ( A ) is linearly related Auxiliary Result: How . . . to u ( A ): u ′ ( A ) = a · u ( A ) + b. Home Page • Let us apply the notion of utility to our problem. Title Page ◭◭ ◮◮ • Usually, we only describe the bounds Y ( t ) = [ Y ( t ) , Y ( t )] for the values t from a grid: t i = t 0 + i · ∆ t. ◭ ◮ • In this case, the utility describing the quality of each Page 7 of 27 estimation has the form u ( Y ( t 0 ) , Y ( t 1 ) , . . . ). Go Back • Let us describe common sense properties of preference Full Screen in terms of utility functions. Close Quit

  8. Need for Data Processing Need to Take . . . 7. Localness Property Dynamic Case • Let us assume that: How Preferences Are . . . Localness Property – the two enclosures Y ( t ) and Y ′ ( t ) differ only for Other Common-Sense . . . moments t ∈ [ t, t ], and Main Result – that Y is preferred to Y ′ ( Y ≥ Y ′ ). How to Compare . . . • This means that, for the user, on the interval [ t, t ], the Auxiliary Result: How . . . bounds Y ( t ) are better than the bounds Y ′ ( t ). Home Page • This preference should not depend on whatever com- Title Page mon bounds Y ( t ) = Y ′ ( t ) we have for t �∈ [ t, t ]. ◭◭ ◮◮ • Formally: ◭ ◮ – if we have bounds Z ( t ) and Z ′ ( t ) for which: Page 8 of 27 ∗ Z ( t ) = Z ′ ( t ) for all t �∈ [ t, t ], and Go Back ∗ Z ( t ) = Y ( t ) and Z ′ ( t ) = Y ′ ( t ) for all t ∈ [ t, t ], Full Screen – then Z should be preferable to Z ′ : Z ≥ Z ′ . Close Quit

  9. Need for Data Processing Need to Take . . . 8. Localness in Terms of Utility Dynamic Case • It is known that preferences are local if and only if How Preferences Are . . . u ( x 1 , . . . , x n ) is: Localness Property Other Common-Sense . . . – additive u ( x 1 , . . . , x n ) = u 1 ( x 1 ) + . . . + u n ( x n ) for Main Result some u i ( x i ); or How to Compare . . . – multiplicative u ( x 1 , . . . , x n ) = u 1 ( x 1 ) · . . . · u n ( x n ). • In our case, we maximize � u ( Y ( t i ) , t i ) or � Auxiliary Result: How . . . u ( Y ( t i ) , t i ), Home Page i i def where u i ( Y ( t i )) = u ( Y ( t i ) , t i ). Title Page • Maximizing the product is equivalent to maximizing ◭◭ ◮◮ its logarithm – which is a sum. ◭ ◮ • So, we always maximize the sum. Page 9 of 27 • When ∆ t → 0, the sum tends to an integral, so we � Go Back maximize the integral u ( Y ( t ) , t ) dt . Full Screen • So, to specify preferences, we must find an appropriate Close function u ( Y , t ). Quit

  10. Need for Data Processing Need to Take . . . 9. Other Common-Sense Properties Dynamic Case • Small changes in time t and enclosure Y ( t ) should lead How Preferences Are . . . to small changes in utility. Localness Property Other Common-Sense . . . • It is therefore reasonable to require that the function Main Result u ( Y , t ) is smooth. How to Compare . . . • Specifically, we require that this function is at least Auxiliary Result: How . . . twice differentiable. Home Page • Preferences should not change: Title Page – if we simply change the unit for measuring time ◭◭ ◮◮ t → λ · t (e.g., from minutes to seconds), ◭ ◮ – or change the starting point t → t + t 0 . Page 10 of 27 • Similarly, we can use different starting points and dif- Go Back ferent units for describing the quantity y . Full Screen • Thus, the preference relation should not change if we replace y with y + y 0 or with λ · y . Close Quit

Download Presentation
Download Policy: The content available on the website is offered to you 'AS IS' for your personal information and use only. It cannot be commercialized, licensed, or distributed on other websites without prior consent from the author. To download a presentation, simply click this link. If you encounter any difficulties during the download process, it's possible that the publisher has removed the file from their server.

Recommend


More recommend