econ 871 solving dsge models using perturbation method
play

Econ 871: Solving DSGE Models Using Perturbation Method Lukasz - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

Econ 871: Solving DSGE Models Using Perturbation Method Lukasz Drozd References Uribe, Schmitt-Grohe (2004), Solving Dynamic General Equilibrium Models Using a Second-Order Approximation to the Policy Function, Journal of Economic


  1. Econ 871: Solving DSGE Models Using Perturbation Method Lukasz Drozd

  2. References • Uribe, Schmitt-Grohe (2004), “Solving Dynamic General Equilibrium Models Using a Second-Order Approximation to the Policy Function,” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, vol. 28, January 2004, pp. 755-775 • Judd (1998), “Numerical Methods in Economics”, chapter 13-14, MIT Press • Klein and Gomme (2006), “Second-order approximation of dynamic models without the use of tensors”, University of Western Ontario manuscript.

  3. • Klein (2000), “Using the generalized Schur form to solve a multivariate linear rational expectations model”, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 24(10), September 2000, pages 1405-1423. • Uhlig (1997), “A Toolkit for Analyzing Dynamic Stochastic Models Easily”, http://www2.wiwi.hu-berlin.de/institute/wpol/html/toolkit.htm • Aruoba, Rubio-Ramirez, Villaverde (2006), “Comparing Solution Meth- ods for Dynamic Equilibrim Economies,” Journal of Economic Dynam- ics & Control 30 (2006) 2509—2531.

  4. Packages That Can Do it For You • Dynare (Platform: standalone or Matlab) — http://www.cepremap.cnrs.fr/dynare/ • Uribe and Schmitt-Grohe (2004) (Platform: Matlab) — http://www.econ.duke.edu/%7Euribe/2nd order • Eric Swanson (Platform: Mathematica) — http://www.ericswanson.us/perturbation.html

  5. Main Idea • Find a case you know how to solve • Rewrite the original problem as a parameterized perturbation from this case • Use Taylor approximation w.r.t. to the perturbation parameter to get an approximate solution • Verify the accurateness!

  6. Strengths • By far the best ‘local’ method: simple, fl exible and very fast... — Excellent packages available online — Possible to take n —th order approximation that makes this method applicable to problems that require at least second order preci- sion (example: portfolio choice problems, see Heathcote and Perri (2007) or Wincoop (2008))

  7. How Does It Work? • Suppose we want to fi nd the lowest value of x that satis fi es the equa- tion x 3 − 4 x + 0 . 1 = 0 . • It is a cubic equation, and suppose we do not know how to solve... • To approximate the solution, we will use the fact that we do know how to solve x 3 − 4 x = 0 . — Factoring x out, we obtain 3 solutions: -2,0,2, the lowest solution is -2

  8. Implementing the Perturbation Method • Step 1: We parameterize the original problem as a perturbation from the case we know how to solve g ( ε ) 3 − 4 g ( ε ) + ε ≡ 0 , all ε where ε is a perturbation parameter, and g ( ε ) is the function that returns the lowest solution. — ε = 0 corresponds to the case we know how to solve — ε = 0 . 1 corresponds to our original problem

  9. • Step 2. Using Taylor’s Theorem, approximate g ( · ) by a polynomial g ( ε ) ' g (0) + g 0 (0) ε + 1 2! g 00 (0) ε 2 .

  10. Caveats The Taylor polynomial always exists, providing f is suitably di ff erentiable. But it need not be useful. Consider the example: ( exp( − 1 /x 2 ) if x > 0; f (x) = 0 if x ≤ 0. The interest is in f is at 0. It turns out that f (0) = f 0 (0) = f 00 (0) = ... = f ( n ) (0) = ... = 0 .

  11. So, the Taylor polynomial of degree n for f around 0 is P n ( x ) = 0 + 0 x + 0 x 2 + ... + 0 x n = 0 , and so for every n , the residual is f ( x ). Clearly in this case, P n tells us nothing useful about the function. Fortunately, the family of smooth functions for which Taylor approximation works, called analytic functions, is quite broad. Most simple functions are analytic, and the family is closed under sums, products and compositions. So, as long as the equation we study is an analytic function, the implicit function g ( ε ) should be analytic as well. (In the above example it is the improper reciprocal that creates a problem.)

  12. • Step 3. Find g (0), g 0 (0) , g 00 (0) using the Implicit Function Theorem — Since we know that our equation holds identically for all ε , in particular, the fi rst and second derivatives at ε = 0 must be zero. Thus, g (0) 3 − 4 g (0) = 0 , 3 g (0) 2 g 0 (0) − 4 g 0 (0) + 1 = 0 , 6 g (0) g 0 (0) 2 + 3 g 00 (0) g (0) 2 − 4 g 00 (0) = 0 .

  13. • From fi rst equation we obtain g (0) = − 2 , • From second equation we obtain g 0 (0) = − 1 8 , • and from third we obtain 3 g 00 (0) = 128 . (Note that g (0) is solved and is then used to solve for g 0 (0) , and both g (0) and g 0 (0) are used to solve for g 00 (0). This is a general property. )

  14. Trust, But Verify • Plugging in to our Taylor expansion, we obtain the approximate solu- tion g (0 . 1) ' − 2 − 1 80 . 1 + 1 3 1280 . 1 2 = − 2 . 01246 , 2 • It is always a good idea to verify the solution by evaluating the resid- uals: ( − 2 . 0134) 3 − 4( − 2 . 0134) + 0 . 1 = − 0 . 00062 . — As we can see, it is pretty close to zero

  15. Higher Order Approximations • In principle, we could go as far as we want — we could take 3rd order approximation, 4th order, etc... • This is the strength of this method — Need a more precise solution? Take a higher order approximation

  16. Solving a Simple RBC Model • As an example, we will now solve a simple RBC model ∞ X β t log( c t ) max E 0 t subject to c t + k t = e z t k α t − 1 , z t = ρz t − 1 + σε t , ε t ˜ N (0 , 1) .

  17. A Note on Notation • Note that in the formulation of the model k is shifted to period t − 1 . This way all t period variables denote variables that are known at period t but not at period t − 1 • You will often encounter such ‘shifted’ notation when an expectation operator is involved

  18. Equilibrium Conditions • The equilibrium conditions of our model are given by = e z t k α c t + k t t − 1 , αe ρz t + σε t +1 k α − 1 1 t = βE t , c t c t +1 z t = ρz t − 1 + σε t , ε t ˜ N (0 , 1) which we can compactly write as αe ρz t + σε t +1 k α − 1 1 t − βE t = 0 . e z t k α e ρz t + σε t +1 k α t − 1 − k t t − k t +1

  19. What Are We Looking For? • This model has a recursive representation (SLP chapter 4), and so we know that we are looking for a policy function k ( k, z ; σ ) such that for all k, z, σ αe ρz + σε k α − 1 1 e z k α − k ( k, z ; σ ) − βE e ρz + σε k α − k ( k ( k, z ; σ ) , ρz + σε ; σ ) = 0. (The expectation operator E is the integral over ε, which is normally distributed with variance 1 and mean 0.) • Our goal is to approximate this function

  20. Closed Form Solution? • Turns out, this particular model has a closed form solution of the form k ( k, z ; σ ) = αβe z k α , where z follows AR(1) process z t = ρz t − 1 + σε t , ε t ˜ N (0 , 1) . — Note that the sample paths of the key variables oscillate around deterministic steady state 1 ¯ k = ( αβ ) 1 − α , z ¯ = 0 • Gives us opportunity to test and better understand the method

  21. Implementing Perturbation Method • To implement the perturbation method we need to fi nd a case we know how to solve • We know how to solve for the deterministic case, which corresponds to σ = 0 — The solution is given by 1 ¯ k = ( αβ ) 1 − α , ¯ = 0 . z • This property makes σ the natural candidate for the perturbation pa- rameter

  22. The Approximation Step • The second step is to use Taylor expansion to approximate the solution from the known one • To fi nd out what we are looking for, we fi rst take the Taylor expansion of the policy function k ( k, z, σ ) ' k (¯ k, 0; 0) + k k ( k − ¯ k ) + k z z + k σ σ + +1 k ) 2 + 1 2 k zz z 2 + 1 2 k σσ σ 2 + 2 k kk ( k − ¯ + k kz ( k − ¯ k ) z + k kσ ( k − ¯ k ) σ + k zσ zσ, where all derivatives are evaluated at the perturbation point (¯ k, 0; 0) .

  23. What Do We Want? • From Taylor’s expansion, we note that — First order approximation requires 4 numbers: k (¯ k, 0; 0) , k k , k z , k σ — Second order approximation additionally requires 6 more numbers: k kk , k σσ , k zz , k zσ , k zk , k kσ • Using equilibrium conditions and the Implicit Function Thmeorem, our task is to fi nd these numbers — The supporting Matlab code for this part can be download from my website

  24. Compact Notation • To simplify notation, let’s de fi ne F ( k, z ; σ ) ≡ H ( k ( k ( k, z ; σ ) , ρz + σε ; σ ) , k ( k, z ; σ ) , k, z ; σ ) ≡ αe ρz + σε k α − 1 1 e z k α − k ( k, z ; σ ) − βE e ρz + σε k α − k ( k ( k, z ; σ ) , ρz + σε ; σ ) . • This way — H i denotes a partial derivative w.r.t. to the i -th argument of H — F k denotes total derivative of H w.r.t. k

  25. First Order Approximation • Need to fi nd k (¯ k, 0; 0) , k k , k z , k σ • To obtain fi rst order approximation, by analogy to our earlier case, we use the fact that optimal policy must obey the following 4 equations: (1) : F (¯ k, 0; 0) = 0 (2) : F k (¯ k, 0; 0) = 0 (3) : F z (¯ k, 0; 0) = 0 (4) : F σ (¯ k, 0; 0) = 0

  26. Results • From (1), we obtain 1 k (¯ k, 0; 0) = ( αβ ) 1 − α — Plugging in α = 1 / 2 , ρ = . 9 and β = . 9 , (1) gives k, 0; 0) = 0 . 45 2 = 0 . 2025 k (¯

  27. • From (2), we obtain H 1 k k k k + H 2 k k + H 3 = 0 . — Evaluating H 1 , H 2 and H 3 for our choice of parameters, (2) gives − 16 . 325 k 2 k + 44 . 440 k k − 18 . 139 = 0 , and solves to k k = 0 . 5 , k k = 2 . 22 . • But, which solution should we choose, and why do we get two? When k k = 2 . 22 the system is explosive — and so on this basis we can clearly reject this solution. In general, we will always get explosive solutions,

Download Presentation
Download Policy: The content available on the website is offered to you 'AS IS' for your personal information and use only. It cannot be commercialized, licensed, or distributed on other websites without prior consent from the author. To download a presentation, simply click this link. If you encounter any difficulties during the download process, it's possible that the publisher has removed the file from their server.

Recommend


More recommend