do brain drain and poverty result from coordination
play

Do brain drain and poverty result from coordination failures? David - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

Do brain drain and poverty result from coordination failures? David de la Croix Fr ed eric Docquier IRES & CORE, UCLouvain FNRS, & IRES, UCLouvain March 2010 Introduction Model Analysis Calibration Results Robustness


  1. Do brain drain and poverty result from coordination failures? David de la Croix Fr´ ed´ eric Docquier IRES & CORE, UCLouvain FNRS, & IRES, UCLouvain March 2010

  2. Introduction Model Analysis Calibration Results Robustness Conclusion Additional S. Endogeneity of the brain drain Brain drain: high-skill people flee their own country. Main factors: • poverty, instability, fractionalization ... (Docquier et al.) • income differentials (Grogger and Hanson) • importance of the skill premium home and abroad (Rosenzweig) In this literature, economic characteristics of countries are treated as exogenous (or instrumented in empirical papers) 2 / 39

  3. Introduction Model Analysis Calibration Results Robustness Conclusion Additional S. Endogeneity of economic performances Brain drain (BD) affects human capital accumulation and economic development at origin • early literature shows that brain drain reduces human capital (Bhagwati and Hamada) • literature in the 90s shows that this is worsened if human capital induces externalities (endogenous growth) • new literature highlights some beneficial effects of the BD (Beine et al.) In this literature, emigration probability is exogenous - the endogeneity of the emigration rate is ignored 3 / 39

  4. Introduction Model Analysis Calibration Results Robustness Conclusion Additional S. Possibility of multiple equilibria Considering the two literatures together, ∃ vicious circles: Poverty at home → flight of the most skilled Brain drain → poverty at home Vicious circles open the possibility of multiple equilibria 1. All the skilled have flew and the country is poor 2. All the skilled decided to stay and the country is developed Reasons ? strategic complementarity between the emigration decision of the skilled: if the neighbor emigrates, it is better for me to emigrate too. Consequence: expectations matter 4 / 39

  5. Introduction Model Analysis Calibration Results Robustness Conclusion Additional S. Some examples of massive BD Massive BD waves • (out) Iran after 1979 • (out) Easter Europe after WWII • (in) Ireland in the 1980s But stronger BD can be found in small islands 5 / 39

  6. Introduction Model Analysis Calibration Results Robustness Conclusion Additional S. Can a ”high brain drain-high poverty” situation be the result of a coordination failure? 6 / 39

  7. Introduction Model Analysis Calibration Results Robustness Conclusion Additional S. Example: Trinidad and Tobago Average skill ratio (H/L) in high-income countries: 0.243 in 2000 Trinidad and Tobago: Skilled to unskilled ratio population (bef. migration): 0.226 Brain drain: 79.03% Productivity relative to developed: 44.3% But if: Brain drain: 0.01% Productivity relative to developed: 68.3% Would that be an equilibrium ? 7 / 39

  8. Introduction Model Analysis Calibration Results Robustness Conclusion Additional S. What we do A Theory Endogenize human capital accumulation, migration and productivity. Possibility of multiple equilibria Identifying country-specific parameters In 15 percent of developing countries (representing about 50 percent of small states), poverty and high brain drain are worsened by a coordination failure. 8 / 39

  9. Introduction Model Analysis Calibration Results Robustness Conclusion Additional S. Technology In each developing country: Y t = A t ( ω L t + H t ) Note: high elasticity of substitution between L an H needed to match data on skill premium. Skilled to unskilled ratio: k t ≡ H t L t Lucas-type externality: A t = Ak α t 9 / 39

  10. Introduction Model Analysis Calibration Results Robustness Conclusion Additional S. Individual migration choice Log utility Income abroad: ¯ A Cost of migration for an individual: ˜ ε i all individuals with migration costs below a critical value find it optimal to emigrate. The critical value is given by ε t ≡ ln ¯ A − ln A − α ln k t decreasing with the skill-ratio k t 10 / 39

  11. Introduction Model Analysis Calibration Results Robustness Conclusion Additional S. Individual migration choice Heterogeneous migration costs ∼ distribution function G (˜ ε ) We will use Gumbel, Logistic and Normal Country-specific parameters m ∈ R (location) and b > 0 (scale) G � e � 1.0 0.8 Example for 0.6 Trinidad and 0.4 Tobago: 0.2 e 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 11 / 39

  12. Introduction Model Analysis Calibration Results Robustness Conclusion Additional S. Population dynamics k t = z t [1 − G ( ε t )] k t : after-migration skill-ratio ; z t : skill-ratio in the ex-ante (before-migration) native labor force Population levels of the two groups: Z s n s Z s t [1 − G ( ε t )] + q n u Z u = t +1 t Z u (1 − q ) n u Z u = t +1 t Assumption: high-skill workers educate all their children whereas low-skill workers only educate a fraction q ∈ (0 , 1) of them. 12 / 39

  13. Introduction Model Analysis Calibration Results Robustness Conclusion Additional S. Population dynamics (2) Resulting difference equation of the first-order: t +1 = 1 − G ( ε t ) q z t +1 = Z s t +1 / Z u n z t + 1 − q 1 − q differential fertility: n = n s / n u 13 / 39

  14. Introduction Model Analysis Calibration Results Robustness Conclusion Additional S. Inter-temporal equilibrium Definition Given an initial skilled to unskilled ratio ¯ z 0 > 0, an inter-temporal equilibrium with migration is a vector of skilled to unskilled ratios + and a vector of poverty indexes { ε t } t ≥ 0 ∈ R ∞ such { z t } t ≥ 0 ∈ R ∞ that z 0 = ¯ z 0 and ∀ t ≥ 0: A − ln A [(1 − G ( ε t )) z t ] α ≡ f ( ε t , z t ) , ε t = ln ¯ (1) 1 − q + 1 − G ( ε t ) q z t +1 = n z t ≡ h ( ε t , z t ) . (2) 1 − q 14 / 39

  15. Introduction Model Analysis Calibration Results Robustness Conclusion Additional S. Incentive constraint Two Assumptions on G , requiring migration to respond sufficiently fast to differential income for large differential Lemma Under Assumptions 1 and 2, for any level z > ˆ z there exists two values of ε , s + ( z t ) > s − ( z t ) , such that the incentive constraint A − ln A [(1 − G ( ε t )) z t ] α ≡ f ( ε t , z t ) ε t = ln ¯ holds. Hence, two levels of brain drain G ( s + ( z )) > G ( s − ( z )) are compatible with one z (for z > ˆ z ) 15 / 39

  16. Introduction Model Analysis Calibration Results Robustness Conclusion Additional S. Dynamics 1 − q + 1 − G ( ε t ) q z t +1 = n z t ≡ h ( ε t , z t ) 1 − q At each t , there are therefore two values of z t +1 compatible with Equations (1)-(2). The dynamics can be written as:  h ( s + ( z t ) , z t )  z t +1 = or h ( s − ( z t ) , z t )  16 / 39

  17. Introduction Model Analysis Calibration Results Robustness Conclusion Additional S. Drawing the dynamic relationship z t +1 low brain drain path h ( s − ( z t ) , z t ) 1 − q z t n 1 − q + q high brain drain path h ( s + ( z t ) , z t ) q 1 − q z t z ˆ 17 / 39

  18. Introduction Model Analysis Calibration Results Robustness Conclusion Additional S. Indeterminacy Some conditions for existence. If one equilibrium exists, an infinite number of equilibria exist ր ... h ( s − ( z + 1 ) , z + 1 ) − → ... ր z + h ( s + ( z + 1 ) , z + 1 = h ( s − (¯ z 0 ) , ¯ z 0 ) − → 1 ) − → ... ր ց ... ¯ z 0 ց ր ... z − 1 = h ( s + (¯ h ( s − ( z − 1 ) , z − z 0 ) , ¯ z 0 ) − → 1 ) − → ... ց h ( s + ( z − 1 ) , z − 1 ) − → ... ց ... 18 / 39

  19. Introduction Model Analysis Calibration Results Robustness Conclusion Additional S. Indeterminacy (2) z t +1 z t +1 h ( s − ( z t ) , z t ) h ( s − ( z t ) , z t ) h ( s + ( z t ) , z t ) h ( s + ( z t ) , z t ) ¯ z t ¯ z t ˆ z 0 ˆ z 0 z z 19 / 39

  20. Introduction Model Analysis Calibration Results Robustness Conclusion Additional S. Data on the labor force by education level The skill-ratio in the resident labor force is given by H j , t k j , t = L 1 j , t + L 2 j , t The numbers of high-skill, low-skill and medium-skill resident workers ( H j , t , L 1 j , t , L 2 j , t ) are available for each country j at time t from the Docquier, Lowell and Marfouk’s database. Return to one year of schooling ∈ [0 . 07; 0 . 10] (Rosenzweig, 2007); low skilled have 15 years less and medium skilled have 6 years less than highly skilled. Hence, ω 1 = 0 . 6 and ω 2 = 0 . 25 Given GDP data, the productivity scale factor of country j is obtained as a residual: Y j , t A j , t = ω 1 L 1 j , t + ω 2 L 2 j , t + H j , t 20 / 39

  21. Introduction Model Analysis Calibration Results Robustness Conclusion Additional S. Calibration of α A t = Ak α t We use data for 1990 and 2000. Regressing ln A j , t on ln k j , t gives: • α = 0 . 277 using a large sample of developing countries (142 observations). Benchmark. • α = 0 . 447 using a larger sample of 195 developing and developed countries. Robustness. Country fixed factor: ln A j = ln A 2000 , j − 0 . 277 × ln k 2000 , j 21 / 39

  22. Introduction Model Analysis Calibration Results Robustness Conclusion Additional S. Calibration of q j Taking differential fertility n = 0 . 605 from Kremer and Chen Dynamics of human capital: z j , 00 = nk j , 75 q j + 1 − q j 1 − q j Solving for q j yields: q j = z j , 00 − nk j , 75 1 + z j , 00 22 / 39

Download Presentation
Download Policy: The content available on the website is offered to you 'AS IS' for your personal information and use only. It cannot be commercialized, licensed, or distributed on other websites without prior consent from the author. To download a presentation, simply click this link. If you encounter any difficulties during the download process, it's possible that the publisher has removed the file from their server.

Recommend


More recommend