chapter 5 short run price competition
play

Chapter 5: Short Run Price Competition Price competition (Bertrand - PDF document

Chapter 5: Short Run Price Competition Price competition (Bertrand competition) A1. Firms meet only once in the market. A2. Homogenous goods. A3. No capacity constraints. Bertrand paradox: same outcome as competitive market...


  1. Chapter 5: Short Run Price Competition • Price competition (Bertrand competition) A1. Firms meet only once in the market. A2. Homogenous goods. A3. No capacity constraints. • Bertrand paradox: same outcome as competitive market... • Solution: relax the assumptions.... – Repeated interaction (Chapter 6) – Product Differentiation (Chapter 7) – There exist capacity constraints; ∗ Cournot Equilibrium 1

  2. 1 The Bertrand Paradox • Duopoly, n = 2 • Because identical goods, consumers buy from the supplier that charges the lowest price. • Market demand: q = D ( p ) • Marginal cost: c • Firm i ’s demand is   D ( p i ) if p i < p j   1 2 D ( p i ) if p i = p j D i ( p i , p j ) =    if p i > p j 0 • Firm i ’s pro fi t is Π i ( p i , p j ) = ( p i − c ) D i ( p i , p j ) De fi nition A Nash equilibrium in price ( Bertrand equilibrium ) is a pair of prices ( p ∗ 1 , p ∗ 2 ) such that each fi rm i ’s price maximizes the pro fi t of i , given the other fi rm’s price. Π i ( p ∗ i , p ∗ j ) ≥ Π i ( p i , p ∗ j ) for i = 1 , 2 and for any p i . 2

  3. • The Bertrand Paradox (1883): The unique equilibrium is p ∗ 2 = c . 1 = p ∗ • Firms price at MC and make no pro fi t. • If asymmetric marginal costs c 1 < c 2 , it is no longer an equilibrium. – p = c 2 ( fi rm 1 sets price lower than c 2 to get the whole market) – fi rm 1 makes Π 1 = ( c 2 − c 1 ) D ( c 2 ) and fi rm 2 has no pro fi t. 3

  4. 2 Solutions to Bertrand Paradox 2.1 Repeated Interaction (relax A1) • Chapter 6 • If fi rms meet more than once, ( p ∗ 1 , p ∗ 2 ) = ( c, c ) is no longer an equilibrium. • Collusive behavior can be sustain by the threat of future losses in a price war. 2.2 Product Differentiation (relax A2) • Chapter 7 • With homogenous product: at equal price, consumers are just indifferent between goods. • If goods are differentiated: ( p ∗ 1 , p ∗ 2 ) = ( c, c ) is no longer an equilibrium. • Example: spacial differentiation 4

  5. 2.3 Capacity Constraints (relax A3) • Edgeworth solution (1887). • If fi rms cannot sell more than they are capable of producing: ( p ∗ 2 ) = ( c, c ) is no longer an equilibrium. 1 , p ∗ • Why? If fi rm 1 has a production capacity smaller than D ( c ) , fi rm 2 can increase his price and get a positive pro fi t. • Example: 2 hotels in a small town, number of beds are fi xed in SR. • The existence of a rigid capacity constraint is a special case of a decreasing returns-to-scale technology. • Why? Firm 1 has a marginal cost of c up to the capacity constraint and then MC = ∞ . 5

  6. 3 Decreasing Returns-to-scale and Capacity Constraints 3.1 Rationing rules • Cost of production C i ( q i ) is increasing and convex, C 0 i ( q i ) > 0 and C 00 i ( q i ) ≥ 0 , for any q i . • If fi rm 1 has a capacity constraint, there exists a residual demand for 2. It depends on the rationing rule. • p 1 < p 2 • Supply of fi rm 1 is q 1 = S 1 ( p 1 ) 3.1.1 The ef fi cient-rationing rule (parallel) • Suppose q 1 < D ( p 1 ) • Residual demand for fi rm 2 is ( D ( p 2 ) − q 1 if D ( p 2 ) > q 1 e D 2 ( p 2 ) = otherwise 0 • It is as if the most eager consumers buy from 1, others from 2. • Ef fi cient because maximizes consumers’ surplus. 6

  7. 3.1.2 The proportional-rationing rule (randomized) • All consumers have the same probability of being rationed. • Demand that cannot be satis fi ed at p 1 : D ( p 1 ) − q 1 • Thus fraction of consumers that cannot buy at p 1 (probability of not being able to buy from 1) is D ( p 1 ) − q 1 D ( p 1 ) • Residual demand for 2 is D 2 ( p 2 ) = D ( p 2 ) D ( p 1 ) − q 1 e D ( p 1 ) • Not ef fi cient for consumers. • However, fi rm 2 prefers this rule because his residual demand is higher for each price. 3.2 Price Competition • Decreasing returns-to-scale softens price competition. Both fi rms’ prices exceed the competitive price. • Demand function is D ( p ) = 1 − p • Inverse demand function is P = P ( q 1 + q 2 ) = 1 − q 1 − q 2 7

  8. • The two fi rms have capacity constraints q i ≤ q i • Investment: c 0 ∈ [ 3 4 , 1] unit cost of acquiring the capacity q i . • Marginal cost of producing is 0 up to q i and then it is ∞ . • Rule is ef fi cient rationing rule. • Price that maximizes (gross) monopoly pro fi t Max p (1 − p ) p is p m = 1 / 2 and thus Π m = 1 / 4 . • Thus the (net) pro fi t of fi rm i is at most 1 / 4 − c 0 q i and is negative for q i ≥ 1 / 3 . • Assume that q i ∈ [0 , 1 / 3] • The unique Nash equilibrium is p ∗ = 1 − ( q 1 + q 2 ) • Proof: – Is it worth charging a lower price? NO because of the capacity constraints. – Is it worth charging a higher price? Pro fi t of i if price p ≥ p ∗ is Π i = q (1 − q − q j ) where q is the quantity 8

  9. sold by fi rm i at price p . Furthermore ∂ Π i ∂ q = 1 − 2 q − q j and ∂ 2 Π i ∂ q 2 < 0 – For q = q i , 1 − 2 q i − q j > 0 as q i < 1 / 3 and q j < 1 / 3 . – Hence, increasing p above p ∗ is not optimal (i.e. lowering q below q i ). • It is as if the 2 fi rms produce at the capacities, and an auctioneer equals supply and demand. • For q i ∈ [0 , 1 / 3] , i = 1 , 2 , the fi rms’ reduced form pro fi t functions are the exact Cournot forms (Levitan and Shubik (1972)) • Gross Π ig ( q i , q j ) = (1 − ( q i + q j )) q i • Net Π ig ( q i , q j ) = (1 − ( q i + q j ) − c 0 ) q i • Same result with the proportional rationing rule (Beckman (1967)). 9

  10. • The assumption of large investment cost insures small capacities, and thus we fi nd a solution. • For larger capacities : no equilibrium in pure strategies, only in mixed strategies . 3.3 Ex ante Investment and ex post price competition • A two stage-game in which 1. fi rms simultaneously choose q i 2. Firms observe the capacities and simultaneously choose p i . • is equivalent to a one-stage game in which fi rms choose quantities q i and an auctioneer determines the market price that clears the market p = P ( q 1 + q 2 ) ; Cournot (1838). • Examples of ex ante choice of scale: – Hotel (cannot adjust its capacity), – Vendor of perishable food. 10

  11. 4 Cournot Competition • Firms choose the quantities simultaneously. • Each fi rm maximizes his pro fi t Π i ( q i , q j ) = q i P ( q i + q j ) − C i ( q i ) • where Π i ( . ) is strictly concave in q i and twice differen- tiable. • FOC i : ∂ P ( . ) + P ( q i + q j ) − ∂ C i ( q i ) q i = 0 ∂ q i ∂ q i ⇒ q i = R i ( q j ) Best response function of i to q j • Lerner index is q i = α i Q $ i = − P 1 ε ∂ P ( . ) Q ∂ qi • where α i is fi rm i ’s market share . • Thus the Lerner index is – proportional to the fi rm’s market share, – inversely proportional to the elasticity of demand. 11

  12. 4.1 Case of linear demand Duopoly • P ( Q ) = 1 − Q • C i ( q i ) = c i q i • What are the reaction functions? R i ( q j ) = 1 − c i − q j 2 for i, j = 1 , 2 and i 6 = j. • What is the Cournot equilibrium? i = 1 − 2 c i + c j q ∗ 3 • What are the pro fi ts of the fi rms? Π i = (1 − 2 c i + c j ) 2 9 • A fi rm’s output decreases with its MC , ∂ q i ∂ c i < 0 . • A fi rm’s output increases with its competitor MC , ∂ q i ∂ cj > 0 . 12

  13. • For more general demand and cost functions, these 2 conditions are true: a. If reaction curves are downward sloping (quantities are strategic substitutes) b. if reaction curves cross only once, and slope of | R 2 | < slope of | R 1 | . Generalization to n fi rms • Q = P n i =1 q i • P ( Q ) = 1 − Q • C i ( q i ) = cq i • FOC i : ∂ P ( . ) ∂ q i + P ( Q ) − ∂ C i ( q i ) q i = 0 ∂ q i ⇒ q i + 1 − Q − c = 0 • and Lerner index $ i = α i ε • Symmetric equilibrium Q = nq , and thus q = 1 − c n + 1 13

  14. • Market price is p = 1 − nq = c + 1 − c n + 1 • and the pro fi t of each fi rm is Π = (1 − c ) 2 ( n + 1) 2 • If n → ∞ , thus p → c . • Exercises 5-3, 5-4, 5-5 14

  15. 5 Concentration Indices • Structure - conduct - performance paradigm • Structure: concentration of the market • Market share of i is Q where i = 1 , ..., n and P n α i = q i i =1 α i = 1 Concentration indices: • m- fi rms concentration ratio ( m < n ) R m = P m i =1 α i – where α 1 ≥ ... ≥ α m ≥ ... ≥ α n – If R m → 0 , low concentration (many fi rms) – If R m → 1 , high concentration (few fi rms): m (usually m = 4 ) or less fi rms produce all of the output of the industry. • Her fi ndahl index R H = 10 , 000 P n i =1 α 2 i – US department of Justice uses this index. The limit for antitrust case is 1,800. – R H → 0 , low concentration – R H → 10 , 000 high concentration 15

  16. 6 Conclusion 16

Download Presentation
Download Policy: The content available on the website is offered to you 'AS IS' for your personal information and use only. It cannot be commercialized, licensed, or distributed on other websites without prior consent from the author. To download a presentation, simply click this link. If you encounter any difficulties during the download process, it's possible that the publisher has removed the file from their server.

Recommend


More recommend