some applications of sdes bsdes with oblique reflection
play

Some Applications of SDEs (BSDEs) with Oblique Reflection PHD - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

ITN-Marie Curie Deterministic and Stochastic Controlled Systems and Application Some Applications of SDEs (BSDEs) with Oblique Reflection PHD Student : GASSOUS M. A. SUPERVISOR : RASCANU A. UNIVERSITY ALEXANDRU IOAN CUZA IAS I


  1. ITN-Marie Curie ”Deterministic and Stochastic Controlled Systems and Application” Some Applications of SDEs (BSDEs) with Oblique Reflection PHD Student : GASSOUS M. A. SUPERVISOR : RASCANU A. UNIVERSITY ”ALEXANDRU IOAN CUZA” IAS ¸I FACULTY OF MATHEMATICS Spring School ”Stochastic Control In Finance” Roscoff 2010.

  2. Introduction � � Applications • Reflected SDE in time-dependent domains • Two examples in Economics (Backward case) • Switching Games (Backward case) � References

  3. Introduction Forward case (solved): - Lions and Sznitman, 1984. - Dupuis and Ishii, 1993.

  4. - Gassous and Rascanu: � dX t + R ( X t ) ∂ϕ ( X t ) ( dt ) ∋ f ( t, X t ) dt + g ( t, X t ) dB t , t > 0 , X 0 = ξ , (1) where ϕ : R d → ] −∞ , + ∞ ] is a proper convex lower-semicontinuous � � function, ∂ϕ is the subdifferential of ϕ and R = d × d ∈ r i,j � R d ; R 2 d � C 2 is a symmetric matrix such that for all x ∈ R d , b 1 c | u | 2 ≤ � R ( x ) u, u � ≤ c | u | 2 , ∀ u ∈ R d (for some c ≥ 1) .

  5. When ϕ = I O , we have X t ∈ C ([0 , ∞ [ , O ) , k t ∈ C ([0 , ∞ [ , R d ) ∩ BV loc ( R + , R d ) , (1) � t � t (2) X t + k t = x 0 + 0 f ( X s ) ds + 0 g ( X s ) dBs, for t ≥ 0 , � t � t (3) � k � t = 0 1 bd ( O ) ( x ( s )) d � k � s , k ( t ) = 0 γ ( x ( s )) d � k � s . (2)

  6. Backward case (in work): - Ramasubramanian, 2002 (special domain) � dY t − R ( Y t ) ∂ϕ ( Y t ) ( dt ) ∋ − f ( t, Y t , Z t ) dt + Z t dB t , t ≥ 0 , (3) Y T = ξ .

  7. Application a k − dimensional standard BM on a com- We consider ( B t ) t ≥ 0 plete probability space (Ω , F , P ), and {F t : t ≥ 0 } the natural fil- tration. 1.Reflected Stochastic differential equations in time-dependent domains Let K be a subset of R + × R n such that the projection of K onto time axis is [0 , T [, and for each 0 ≤ t < T, K ( t ) = { x ∈ R n : ( t, x ) ∈ K } is a bounded connected open set in R n . Let n ( t, x ) be the unit inward normal of K ( t ) and → γ be the unit inward normal vector field on ∂K.

  8. Theorem Suppose that → γ · n ≥ c 0 on ∂K for some c 0 > 0 . Then for each ( s, x ) ∈ K with s < T, there is a unique pair of adapted continuous processes ( X s,x , L s,x ) s.t. t, X s,x ∈ K for t ∈ [ s, T [ , with X s,x � � ( i ) = x, s t L s,x is a nondecreasing process with L s,x � � , t ∈ [ s, T [ ( ii ) = 0 s.t. s t � t L s,x s 1 ∂K ( r, X r ) dL s,x = r , t � t � t � t X s,x s b ( r, X s,x s σ ( r, X s,x s n ( r, X s,x ) dL s,x ( iii ) = x + ) ds + ) dB r + r . r r r t Proof We remark that the last equation is equivalent to an equation with an oblique reflection vector field n verified by the time-space diffusion process (t, X s,x ) in K. t

  9. 2. Two examples in Economics (BSDE) : We consider the RBSDE in an d − dimensional positive orthant G x ∈ R d : x i > 0 , 1 ≤ i ≤ d � � with oblique reflection G = : � T � T � T Y ( t ) = ξ + b ( s, Y ( s )) ds + R ( s, Y ( s )) dK ( s ) − t � Z ( s ) , dB ( s ) t t with Y ( · ) ∈ G for all 0 ≤ t ≤ T ; and K i (0) = 0 , K i ( · ) continuous, nondecreasing with � t K i ( t ) = (3) 0 I { 0 } ( Y i ( s )) dK i ( s ) . This equation has a unique solution (see [1]).

  10. ⋆ Backward stochastic analogue of subsidy-surplus model considered in Ramasubramanian [1] We consider an economy with d interdependent sectors, with the following interpretation (a) Y i ( t ) = current surplus in Sector i at time t ; (b) K i ( t ) = cumulative subsidy given to Sector i over [0 , t ]; (c) ξ i = desired surplus in Sector i at time T ; � t (d) s b i ( u, Y ( u )) du = net production of Sector i over [ s, t ] due to evolution of the system; this being negative indicates there is net consumption;

  11. � t s r − (e) ij ( u, Y ( u )) dK j = amount of subsidy for Sector j mobi- lized from Sector i over [ s, t ]; � t s r + (f) ij ( u, Y ( u )) dK j = amount of subsidy mobilized for Sector j which is actually used in Sector i (but not as subsidy in Sector i ) over [ s, t ]. The condition (3) in RBSDE ( ξ, b, R ) means that subsidy for Sector i can be mobilized only when Sector i has no surplus. (The uniform spectral radius condition would mean that the sub- sidy mobilized from external sources is nonzero; so this would be an ‘open’ system in the jargon of economics).

  12. ⋆ Backward stochastic (oblique) analogue of projected dy- namical system Suppose the system represents d traders each specializing in a different commodity. For this model we assume: r ij ( · , · ) ≤ 0 , i � = j ; Y i ( t ) = current price of Commodity i at time t ; there is a price floor viz. prices cannot be negative; K i ( t ) = cumulative adjustment involved in the price of Com- modity i over [0 , t ]; b i ( t, Y ( t )) dt = infinitesimal change in price of Commodity i due to evolution of the system;

  13. ξ i = desired price level of Commodity i at time T . Condition (3) then means that adjustment dK i ( t ) can take place only if the price of Commodity i is zero. � t s r − ij ( u, Y ( u )) dK j ( u ) = adjustment from Trader i when price of Commodity j is zero. Note that dK j ( · ) can be viewed upon as a sort of artificial/forced infinitesimal consumption when the price of Commodity j is zero to boost up the price;

  14. hence r − ij ( t, Y ( t )) dK j ( t ) is the contribution of Trader i towards this forced consumption. (As before, the uniform spectral radius condition) implies that there is nonzero ‘external adjustment’, like perhaps governmental intervention/consumption to boost prices when prices crash).

  15. 3. Switching Games(Ying-Hu and Shanjian Tang) Consider two players I and II, who use their respective switching control processes a ( · ) and b ( · ) to control the following BSDE : A ( a ) ( T ) − A ( a ) ( t ) B ( b ) ( T ) − B ( b ) ( t ) � � � � U ( t ) = ξ + − � T � T f ( s, U ( s ) , V ( s ) , a ( s ) , b ( s )) ds − + V ( s ) dB ( s ) , t t A a ( . ) ( · ) and B b ( · ) ( · ) are the cost processes associated where with the switching control processes a ( · ) and b ( · ). Under suitable conditions, the above BSDE has a unique adapted solution, denoted by ( U a ( · ) ,b ( · ) , V a ( · ) ,b ( · ) ).

  16. Player I chooses the switching control a ( · ) from a given finite set to minimize the cost min −− > J ( a ( · ) , b ( · )) = U a ( · ) ,b ( · ) (0) and each of his instantaneous switching from one scheme i ∈ Λ ′ ∈ Λ incurs a positive cost which to another different scheme i � i, i ′ � . will be specified by the function k While Player II chooses the switching control b ( · ) from a given finite set Π to maximize the cost max −− > J ( a ( · ) , b ( · )) and each of his instantaneous switching from one scheme j ∈ Π to another different scheme j ′ ∈ Π incurs a positive cost which will be specified by the function l ( j, j ′ ),

  17. � ∞ � Let j =0 increasing sequence of stopping time, α j F θ j − measurable θ j r.v with value in Λ , then a admissible switching strategy for player I: N � a ( s ) = α 0 χ { θ 0 } ( s ) + α j − 1 χ ( θ j − 1 ,θ j ] ( s ) , j =1 therefore N − 1 A a ( · ) ( s ) = � � � χ [ θ j ,T ] ( s ) . k α j − 1 , α j j =1

  18. We are interested in the existence and the construction of the value process as well as the saddle point. The solution of the above-stated switching game will appeal the reflected backward stochastic differential equation with oblique reflection:

  19. � T  � �  Y i,j ( t ) = ξ i,j + f s, Y ij ( s ) , Z ij ( s ) , i, j ds    t   � T � T � T     − dK ij ( s ) + dL ij ( s ) − Z ij ( s ) dB ( s )     t t t   � � i, i ′ ��   Y i,j ( t ) ≤ min Y i ′ ,j ( t ) + k ,    i ′ � = i     � � j, j ′ ��   Y i,j ( t ) ≥ max Y i,j ′ ( t ) − l  , (4) i ′ � = i   T   i, i ′ ��   � �  �  dK ij ( s ) = 0 ,   Y i,j ( s ) − min Y i ′ ,j ( s ) + k    i ′ � = i    0     T   j, j ′ ��   � �  �  dL ij ( s ) = 0 .   Y i,j ( s ) − max Y i,j ′ ( t ) − l    i ′ � = i    0

  20. We define ( a ∗ ( · ) , b ∗ ( · )) as follows: θ ∗ 0 := 0 , τ ∗ 0 := 0; α ∗ 0 := i, β ∗ 0 := j. We define stopping times θ ∗ p , τ ∗ p ; α ∗ p , β ∗ p in the following inductive manner: θ ∗ p := inf { s ≥ θ ∗ p − 1 ∧ τ ∗ p − 1 : Y α ∗ p − 1 ( s ) = min { Y i ′ ,β ∗ p − 1 ( s ) p − 1 ,β ∗ i ′ � = i ′ ) }} ∧ T, + k ( α ∗ p − 1 , i τ ∗ p := inf { s ≥ θ ∗ p − 1 ∧ τ ∗ p − 1 : Y α ∗ p − 1 ( s ) = max { Y α ∗ p − 1 ,j ′ ( s ) p − 1 ,β ∗ j ′ � = j ′ ) }} ∧ T. − l ( β ∗ p − 1 , j

  21. Theorem Under the usual hypothesis. Let ( Y, Z, K, L ) solution in the space S 2 × M 2 × N 2 × N 2 to RBSDE (4 ). Then we have the represen- tation : U a ( · ) Y ij ( t ) = ess inf ( t ) . j a ( · ) ∈A i t

Download Presentation
Download Policy: The content available on the website is offered to you 'AS IS' for your personal information and use only. It cannot be commercialized, licensed, or distributed on other websites without prior consent from the author. To download a presentation, simply click this link. If you encounter any difficulties during the download process, it's possible that the publisher has removed the file from their server.

Recommend


More recommend