portfolio choice under space time monotone criteria kick
play

Portfolio choice under space - time monotone criteria Kick - off - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

Portfolio choice under space - time monotone criteria Kick - off Workshop RICAM September 2008 Thaleia Zariphopoulou The University of Texas at Austin 1 Performance measurement of investment strategies 2 Market environment Riskless and


  1. Portfolio choice under space - time monotone criteria Kick - off Workshop RICAM September 2008 Thaleia Zariphopoulou The University of Texas at Austin 1

  2. Performance measurement of investment strategies 2

  3. Market environment Riskless and risky securities W = ( W 1 , . . . , W d ) • (Ω , F , P ) ; standard Brownian Motion • Traded securities � � ⎧ dS i t = S i µ i t dt + σ i S i t · dW t 0 > 0 , ⎪ t ⎨ 1 ≤ i ≤ k ⎪ dB t = r t B t dt , B 0 = 1 ⎩ µ t , r t ∈ R , σ i t ∈ R d bounded and F t -measurable stochastic processes • Postulate existence of an F t -measurable stochastic process λ t ∈ R d satisfying 1 = σ T µ t − r t 1 t λ t • No assumptions on market completeness 3

  4. Market environment π 0 t , π t = ( π 1 t , . . . , π i t , . . . , π k • Self-financing investment strategies t ) • Present value of this allocation k π i � X t = t i =0 k π i t σ i � dX t = t · ( λ t dt + dW t ) i =1 = σ t π t · ( λ t dt + dW t ) 4

  5. Investment performance process U ( x, t ) is an F t -adapted process, t ≥ 0 • The mapping x → U ( x, t ) is increasing and concave • For each self-financing strategy, represented by π , the associated (discounted) wealth X π t satisfies E P ( U ( X π t , t ) | F s ) ≤ U ( X π s , s ) , 0 ≤ s ≤ t • There exists a self-financing strategy, represented by π ∗ , for which the associated (discounted) wealth X π ∗ satisfies t E P ( U ( X π ∗ t , t ) | F s ) = U ( X π ∗ s , s ) , 0 ≤ s ≤ t 5

  6. Optimality across times U ( x, t ) ∈ F t | | 0 U ( x, s ) ∈ F s U ( x, t ) ∈ F t | | | 0 E ( U ( X π U ( x, s ) = sup t , t ) |F s , X s = x ) A The traditional value function is a special case of the above, defined only for t ∈ [0 , T ] and with (terminal) condition U ( x, T ) = u ( x ) , U ( x, T ) ∈ F 0 6

  7. The forward performance SPDE 7

  8. The forward performance SPDE Let U ( x, t ) be an F t − measurable process such that the mapping x → U ( x, t ) is increasing and concave. Let also U = U ( x, t ) be the solution of the stochastic partial differential equation 2 � � � σσ + A ( Uλ + a ) dU = 1 � � � dt + a · dW A 2 U 2 where a = a ( x, t ) is an F t − adapted process, while A = ∂ ∂x . Then U ( x, t ) is a forward performance process. • The process a may depend on t, x, U, its spatial derivatives etc. • Note that in the traditional (backward) case, the volatility process is fixed 8

  9. Optimal portfolios and wealth At the optimum • The optimal portfolio vector π ∗ is given in the feedback form t , t ) = − σ + A ( Uλ + a ) t = π ∗ ( X ∗ π ∗ ( X ∗ t , t ) A 2 U • The optimal wealth process X ∗ solves t = − σσ + A ( Uλ + a ) dX ∗ ( X ∗ t , t ) ( λdt + dW t ) A 2 U 9

  10. The zero volatility case: a ( x, t ) ≡ 0 10

  11. Space-time monotone performance process The forward performance SPDE simplifies to 2 � � � σσ + A ( Uλ ) dU = 1 � � � dt A 2 U 2 The process � t 2 ds � � σ s σ + � U ( x, t ) = u ( x, A t ) with A t = s λ s � � � 0 with u : R × [0 , + ∞ ) → R , increasing and concave with respect to x , and solving u t u xx = 1 2 u 2 x is a solution. MZ (2006) Berrier, Rogers and Tehranchi (2007) 11

  12. Performance measurement time t 1 , information F t 1 110 risk premium 109.8 � t 1 109.6 | λ | 2 ds A t 1 = u(x,t 1 ) 109.4 0 109.2 109 1 0.8 1 0.6 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.4 Time 0.2 Wealth 0.2 0 0 ��� ��� A t 1 + u ( x, t 1 ) � � � � U ( x, t 1 ) = u ( x, A t 1 ) ∈ F t 1 12

  13. Performance measurement time t 2 , information F t 2 110 risk premium 105 � t 2 | λ | 2 ds 100 A t 2 = u(x,t 2 ) 0 95 90 1 0.8 1 0.6 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.4 Time 0.2 Wealth 0.2 0 0 ��� ��� A t 2 + u ( x, t 2 ) � � � � U ( x, t 2 ) = u ( x, A t 2 ) ∈ F t 2 13

  14. Performance measurement time t 3 , information F t 3 110 105 risk premium 100 � t 3 95 | λ | 2 ds A t 3 = 90 u(x,t 3 ) 0 85 80 75 1 0.8 1 0.6 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.4 Wealth 0.2 0.2 Time 0 0 ��� ��� A t 3 + u ( x, t 3 ) � � � � U ( x, t 3 ) = u ( x, A t 3 ) ∈ F t 3 14

  15. Forward performance measurement time t , information F t u(x,t) market Time Wealth ��� ��� MI ( t ) u ( x, t ) + � � � � 15 U ( x, t ) = u ( x, A t ) ∈ F t

  16. Properties of the performance process U ( x, t ) = u ( x, A t ) • the deterministic risk preferences u ( x, t ) are compiled with � t 0 | λ | 2 ds the stochastic market input A t = • the evolution of preferences is “deterministic” • the dynamic risk preferences u ( x, t ) reflect the risk tolerance and the impatience of the investor 16

  17. Optimal allocations 17

  18. Optimal allocations • Let X ∗ t be the optimal wealth, and A t the time-rescaling processes dX ∗ t = σ t π ∗ t · ( λ t dt + dW t ) dA t = | λ t | 2 dt • Define r ( x, t ) = − u x ( x, t ) R ∗ t � r ( X ∗ t , A t ) u xx ( x, t ) Optimal portfolios π ∗ t = σ + t λ t R ∗ t 18

  19. A system of SDEs at the optimum dX ∗ t = r ( X ∗ ⎧ t , A t ) λ t · ( λ t dt + dW t ) ⎨ dR ∗ t = r x ( X ∗ t , A t ) dX ∗ ⎩ t π ∗ t = σ + t λ t R ∗ t The optimal wealth and portfolios are explicitly constructed if the function r ( x, t ) is known 19

  20. Concave utility inputs and increasing harmonic functions 20

  21. Concave utility inputs and increasing harmonic functions There is a one-to-one correspondence between strictly concave solutions u ( x, t ) to u 2 u t = 1 x 2 u xx and strictly increasing solutions to h t + 1 2 h xx = 0 21

  22. Concave utility inputs and increasing harmonic functions • Increasing harmonic function h : R × [0 , + ∞ ) → R is represented as e yx − 1 2 y 2 t − 1 � h ( x, t ) = ν ( dy ) y R • The associated utility input u : R × [0 , + ∞ ) → R is then given by the concave function � t � x u ( x, t ) = − 1 0 e − h ( − 1) ( x,s )+ s 0 e − h ( − 1) ( z, 0) dz h ( − 1) ( x, s ) , s � � ds + 2 h x 2 The support of the measure ν plays a key role in the form of the range of h and, as a result, in the form of the domain and range of u as well as in its asymptotic behavior (Inada conditions) 22

  23. Examples 23

  24. Measure ν has compact support ν ( dy ) = δ 0 , where δ 0 is a Dirac measure at 0 Then, e yx − 1 2 y 2 t − 1 � h ( x, t ) = δ 0 = x y R and � t � x u ( x, t ) = − 1 0 e − x + s 0 e − z dz = 1 − e − x + t 2 ds + 2 2 24

  25. Measure ν has compact support ν ( dy ) = b 2 ( δ a + δ − a ) , a, b > 0 δ ± a is a Dirac measure at ± a Then, h ( x, t ) = b ae − 1 2 a 2 t sinh ( ax ) If, a = 1 , then − e t � � u ( x, t ) = 1 − t � � � � � � x 2 + b 2 e − t x 2 + b 2 e − t ln x + x − b 2 x 2 2 If a � = 1 , then √ a e − at + (1 + √ a ) x � √ a x + � � 1+ 1 ax 2 + βe − at u ( x, t ) = ( √ a ) β √ a 1 −√ a t e 2 � 1+ 1 a − 1 √ a � √ a x + � ax 2 + βe − at 25

  26. Measure ν has infinite support 2 y 2 dy 1 2 π e − 1 √ ν ( dy ) = Then � x � � z 2 x 2 dz √ t + 1 h ( x, t ) = F F ( x ) = 0 e and √ � � F ( − 1) ( x ) − u ( x, t ) = F t + 1 26

  27. Optimal processes and increasing harmonic functions 27

  28. Optimal processes and risk tolerance ⎧ dX ∗ t = r ( X ∗ t , A t ) λ t · ( λ t dt + dW t ) ⎨ dR ∗ t = r x ( X t , A t ) dX ∗ ⎩ t Local risk tolerance function and fast diffusion equation r t + 1 2 r 2 r xx = 0 r ( x, t ) = − u x ( x, t ) u xx ( x, t ) 28

  29. Local risk tolerance and increasing harmonic functions If h : R × [0 , + ∞ ) → R is an increasing harmonic function then r : R × [0 , + ∞ ) → R + given by R e yh ( − 1) ( x,t ) − 1 2 y 2 t ν ( dy ) � h ( − 1) ( x, t ) , t � � r ( x, t ) = h x = is a risk tolerance function solving the FDE 29

  30. Optimal portfolio and optimal wealth • Let h be an increasing solution of the backward heat equation h t + 1 2 h xx = 0 and h ( − 1) stands for its spatial inverse • Let the market input processes A and M by defined by � t � t 0 | λ | 2 ds A t = and M t = 0 λ · dW • Then the optimal wealth and optimal portfolio processes are given by h ( − 1) ( x, 0) + A t + M t , A t X ∗ ,x � � = h t and X ∗ ,x π ∗ � h ( − 1) � � � σ + t = h x , A t , A t t λ t t 30

  31. Complete construction Utility inputs and harmonic functions u 2 u t = 1 h t + 1 x ⇐ ⇒ 2 h xx = 0 2 u xx Harmonic functions and positive Borel measures h ( x, t ) ⇐ ⇒ ν ( dy ) Optimal wealth process � t X ∗ ,x = h h ( − 1) ( x, 0) + A + M, A � � M = 0 λ · dW s , � M � = A Optimal portfolio process π ∗ ,x = h x h ( − 1) ( X ∗ ,x , A ) , A σ + λ � � The measure ν emerges as the defining element ⇒ ⇒ ν h u How do we choose ν and what does it represent for the investor’s risk attitude ? 31

  32. Inferring investor’s preferences 32

  33. Calibration of risk preferences to the market Given the desired distributional properties of his/her optimal wealth in a specific market environment, what can we say about the investor’s risk preferences? Investor’s investment targets • Desired future expected wealth • Desired distribution References Sharpe (2006) Sharpe-Golstein (2005) 33

Download Presentation
Download Policy: The content available on the website is offered to you 'AS IS' for your personal information and use only. It cannot be commercialized, licensed, or distributed on other websites without prior consent from the author. To download a presentation, simply click this link. If you encounter any difficulties during the download process, it's possible that the publisher has removed the file from their server.

Recommend


More recommend