modeling portfolios that contain risky assets stochastic
play

Modeling Portfolios that Contain Risky Assets Stochastic Models II: - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

Modeling Portfolios that Contain Risky Assets Stochastic Models II: Portfolios with Risky Assets C. David Levermore University of Maryland, College Park Math 420: Mathematical Modeling April 3, 2012 version 2011 Charles David Levermore c


  1. Modeling Portfolios that Contain Risky Assets Stochastic Models II: Portfolios with Risky Assets C. David Levermore University of Maryland, College Park Math 420: Mathematical Modeling April 3, 2012 version � 2011 Charles David Levermore c

  2. Modeling Portfolios that Contain Risky Assets Risk and Return I: Introduction II: Markowitz Portfolios III: Basic Markowitz Portfolio Theory Portfolio Models I: Portfolios with Risk-Free Assets II: Long Portfolios III: Long Portfolios with a Safe Investment Stochastic Models I: One Risky Asset II: Portfolios with Risky Assets Optimization I: Model-Based Objective Functions II: Model-Based Portfolio Management III: Conclusion

  3. Stochastic Models II: Portfolios with Risky Assets 1 . IID Models for Markets 2 . IID Models for Markowitz Portfolios 3 . Estimators for Growth Rate Mean and Variance

  4. Stochastic Models II: Portfolios with Risky Assets We now consider a market of N risky assets. Let { s i ( d ) } D h d =0 be a share price history of asset i . Let { r i ( d ) } D h d =1 and { x i ( d ) } D h d =1 be the associated return rate and growth rate histories, where � � � � s i ( d ) s i ( d ) r i ( d ) = D s i ( d − 1) − 1 x i ( d ) = D log , . s i ( d − 1) Because each s i ( d ) is positive, each r i ( d ) is in ( − D, ∞ ) while each x i ( d ) is in ( −∞ , ∞ ) . Let r ( d ) and x ( d ) be the N -vectors     r 1 ( d ) x 1 ( d ) . . . . r ( d ) = x ( d ) = .  , .  .       r N ( d ) x N ( d ) The return rate and growth rate histories can then be expressed simply as { r ( d ) } D h d =1 and { x ( d ) } D h d =1 respectively.

  5. IID Models for Markets. An IID model for this market draws D h random vectors { R ( d ) } D h d =1 from a fixed probablity density q ( R ) over ( − D, ∞ ) N . Such a model is reasonable if the points { ( d, r ( d )) } D h d =1 are distributed in a way that is uniform in d . This is hard to visualize when N is not small. However, a necessary condition for the entire market to have an IID model is that each asset has an IID model. This can be visualized for each as- set by plotting the points { ( d, r i ( d )) } D h d =1 in the dr -plane and seeing if they appear to be distributed in a way that is uniform in d . Similar visual tests based on pairs of assets can be carried out by plotting the points { ( d, r i ( d ) , r j ( d )) } D h d =1 in R 3 with an interactive 3D graphics package. Remark. Such visual tests can only warn you when IID models might not be appropriate for describing the data. There are also statistical tests that can play this role. There is no visual or statistical test that can insure the validity of using an IID model for a market. However, due to their simplicity, IID models are often used unless there is a good reason not to use them.

  6. After you have decided to use an IID model for the market, you must gather statistical information about the return rate probability density q ( R ) . The mean vector µ and covariance matrix Ξ of R are given by � � T q ( R ) d R . µ = R q ( R ) d R , Ξ = ( R − µ )( R − µ ) Given any sample { R ( d ) } D h d =1 drawn from q ( R ) , these have the unbiased estimators D h D h w ( d ) T . ˆ � � µ = ˆ w ( d ) R ( d ) , Ξ = w ( R ( d ) − ˆ µ ) ( R ( d ) − ˆ µ ) 1 − ¯ d =1 d =1 If we assume that such a sample is given by the return rate data { r ( d ) } D h d =1 then these estimators are given in terms of the vector m and matrix V by ˆ µ = m , ˆ Ξ = D V .

  7. IID Models for Markowitz Portfolios. Recall that the value of a portfolio that holds a risk-free balance b rf ( d ) with return rate µ rf and n i ( d ) shares of asset i during trading day d is N � 1 + 1 � � Π( d ) = b rf ( d ) + n i ( d ) s i ( d ) . D µ rf i =1 We will assume that Π( d ) > 0 for every d . Then the return rate r ( d ) and growth rate x ( d ) for this portfolio on trading day d are given by � � � � Π( d ) Π( d ) r ( d ) = D Π( d − 1) − 1 x ( d ) = D log , . Π( d − 1) Recall that the return rate r ( d ) for the Markowitz portfolio associated with the distribution f can be expressed in terms of the vector r ( d ) as T f ) µ rf + f T r ( d ) . r ( d ) = (1 − 1

  8. This implies that if the underlying market has an IID model with return rate probability density q ( R ) then the Markowitz portfolio with distribution f has the IID model with return rate probability density q f ( R ) given by � � T f ) µ rf − R T f � q f ( R ) = R − (1 − 1 q ( R ) d R . δ Here δ ( · ) denotes the Dirac delta distribution , which can be defined by the property that for every sufficiently nice function ψ ( R ) � � T f ) µ rf − R T f � � T f ) µ rf + R T f � ψ ( R ) δ R − (1 − 1 d R = ψ (1 − 1 . Hence, for every sufficiently nice function ψ ( R ) we have the formula � � � Ex ψ ( R ) = ψ ( R ) q f ( R ) d R �� � T f ) µ rf − R T f � = ψ ( R ) δ R − (1 − 1 q ( R ) d R d R � � T f ) µ rf + R T f � = (1 − 1 q ( R ) d R . ψ

  9. We can thereby compute the mean µ and variance ξ of q f ( R ) to be � � T f ) µ rf + R T f � µ = Ex( R ) = (1 − 1 q ( R ) d R T �� � � T f ) µ rf = (1 − 1 q ( R ) d R + R q ( R ) d R f T f ) µ rf + µ T f , = (1 − 1 � 2 q ( R ) d R d R � � � ( R − µ ) 2 � T f ) µ rf + R T f − µ ξ = Ex = (1 − 1 � 2 q ( R ) d R = � � � T f − µ T f f T ( R − µ )( R − µ ) T f q ( R ) d R = R �� � = f T T q ( R ) d R f = f T Ξ f , ( R − µ )( R − µ ) where we have used the facts that � � q ( R ) d R = 1 , R q ( R ) d R = µ , � T q ( R ) d R = Ξ . ( R − µ )( R − µ )

  10. µ = m and ˆ Because µ and Ξ have the unbiased estimators ˆ Ξ = D V , we see from the foregoing formulas that µ and ξ have the unbiased estimators T f ) + m T f , ξ = D f T Vf . ˆ µ = µ rf (1 − 1 ˆ The idea now is to treat the Markowitz portfolio as a single risky asset that can be modeled by the IID process associated with the growth rate probability density p f ( X ) given by � � 1 �� 1 D X − 1 D X . p f ( X ) = q f D e e The mean γ and variance θ of X are given by � � ( X − γ ) 2 p f ( X ) d X . γ = X p f ( X ) d X , θ = We know from our study of one risky asset that γ is a good proxy for return, � 1 while D θ is a good proxy for risk. We therefore would like to estimate γ µ and ˆ and θ in terms of ˆ ξ .

  11. Estimators for Growth Rate Mean and Variance. Introduce the function � � e τX �� K ( τ ) = log Ex . 1 D X ) = e K ( 1 1 D X − 1) and Ex( e D ) , we have Because R = D ( e � e K ( 1 � D ) − 1 µ = Ex( R ) = D . � D X − e K ( 1 1 � D X ) = e K ( 2 2 D ) D ) , we have Because R − µ = D and Ex( e e � e K ( 2 D ) − e 2 K ( 1 � � ( R − µ ) 2 � = D 2 D ) ξ = Ex . Because e K ( 1 D ) = 1 + µ D , we see that ξ e K ( 2 D ) − 2 K ( 1 D ) = 1 + ( D + µ ) 2 . Therefore knowing µ and ξ is equivalent to knowing K ( 1 D ) and K ( 2 D ) .

  12. The function K ( τ ) is the cumulant generating function for X because it recovers the cumulants { κ m } ∞ m =1 of X by the formula κ m = K ( m ) (0) . In particular, you can check that K ′ (0) = γ , K ′′ (0) = θ . Because K (0) = 0 , we interpolate the values K (0) , K ( 1 D ) , and K ( 2 D ) with a quadratic polynomial to construct an estimator ˆ K ( τ ) of K ( τ ) as � D 2 K ( τ ) = τD K ( 1 � τ − 1 � K ( 2 D ) − 2 K ( 1 � ˆ D ) + τ D ) . 2 D γ and ˆ We then construct estimators ˆ θ by K ′ (0) = D K ( 1 D ) − 1 � K ( 2 D ) − 2 K ( 1 � γ = ˆ ˆ D ) 2 D � � 1 + µ ξ � � − 1 = D log 2 D log 1 + , ( D + µ ) 2 D � � = D 2 log K ′′ (0) = D 2 � K ( 2 D ) − 2 K ( 1 � ξ θ = ˆ ˆ D ) 1 + . ( D + µ ) 2

  13. γ and ˆ Upon replacing the µ and ξ in the foregoing estimators for ˆ θ with the T f ) + m T f and ˆ ξ = D f T Vf , we obtain the new estimators ˆ µ = µ rf (1 − 1 estimators 1 + D f T Vf � � 1 + ˆ µ � � − 1 γ = D log ˆ 2 D log , µ ) 2 ( D + ˆ D 1 + D f T Vf � � θ = D 2 log ˆ . µ ) 2 ( D + ˆ Finally, if we assume D is large in the sense that f T Vf � � ˆ µ � � � � � � � << 1 , � << 1 , � � � � � � D D � � then, by keeping the leading order of each term, we arrive at the estimators ˆ θ � T f � T f − 1 2 f T Vf , D = f T Vf . ˆ γ = µ rf 1 − 1 + m

  14. Remark. The estimators ˆ γ and ˆ θ given above have at least three potential sources of error: µ and ˆ • the estimators ˆ ξ upon which they are based, • the interpolant ˆ K ( τ ) used to estimate γ and θ from µ and ξ , • the “large D ” approximation made at the bottom of the previous page. These approximations all assume that the return rate distribution for each Markowitz portfolio is described by a density q f ( R ) that is narrow enough for some moment beyond the second to exist. The last approximation also assumes both that 1 D m and 1 D V are small and that f is not very large. These assumptions should be examined carefully in volatile markets.

Download Presentation
Download Policy: The content available on the website is offered to you 'AS IS' for your personal information and use only. It cannot be commercialized, licensed, or distributed on other websites without prior consent from the author. To download a presentation, simply click this link. If you encounter any difficulties during the download process, it's possible that the publisher has removed the file from their server.

Recommend


More recommend