growth optimality against underperformance
play

Growth-Optimality against Underperformance Greg Zitelli University - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

Growth-Optimality against Underperformance Greg Zitelli University of California, Irvine March 2016 Growth-Optimality against Underperformance University of California, Irvine Large Deviation Theory (Markovs Inequality) If X 0 is a


  1. Growth-Optimality against Underperformance Greg Zitelli University of California, Irvine March 2016 Growth-Optimality against Underperformance University of California, Irvine

  2. Large Deviation Theory (Markov’s Inequality) If X ≥ 0 is a random variable and x > 0 , then the Markov inequality is: x · P [ X ≥ x ] ≤ E [ X ] P [ X ≥ x ] ≤ E [ X ] x Now let X i be random variables, so that for any θ > 0 and x ∈ R we have � � e − θ � T i =1 X i � T � E 1 � e − θ � T i =1 X i ≥ e − θTx � � X i ≤ x = P P ≤ e − θTx T i =1 Growth-Optimality against Underperformance University of California, Irvine

  3. Large Deviation Theory (Chernoff bounds) � � e − θ � T i =1 X i � T � E 1 � i =1 X i ≥ e − θTx � e − θ � T � P X i ≤ x = P ≤ T e − θTx i =1 If the X i are independent, we can split the expectation into the product, so it follows that � T � T 1 � e − θ � T � = e θTx + � T i =1 log E [ e − θXi ] � ≤ e θTx � i =1 X i X i ≤ x P E T i =1 i =1 Growth-Optimality against Underperformance University of California, Irvine

  4. Large Deviation Theory (Chernoff bounds) � T � T 1 � e − θ � T � = e θTx + � T i =1 log E [ e − θXi ] � ≤ e θTx � i =1 X i X i ≤ x P E T i =1 i =1 The function ∞ κ n � � � e θX i n ! θ n λ i ( θ ) = log E = n =1 is called the cumulant generating function for X i , where κ 1 = E [ X i ] and κ 2 = var ( X i ) . For θ > 0 and X i independent our bound is now � T � 1 ≤ e θT ( x + 1 � T i =1 λ i ( − θ ) ) � P X i ≤ x T T i =1 Growth-Optimality against Underperformance University of California, Irvine

  5. Large Deviation Theory (Chernoff bounds) Since this holds for all θ > 0 , we have T � � 1 � T θ> 0 e θT ( x + 1 i =1 λ i ( − θ ) ) � P X i ≤ x ≤ inf T T i =1 If the X i are i.i.d. then we have � � � T � 1 2 θ 2 − ... ] � T θT x + λ 1 ( − θ ) � e inf θ> 0 [ ( x − κ 1 ) θ + κ 2 � P X i ≤ x ≤ inf θ> 0 e = T i =1 If x − κ 1 = x − E [ X 1 ] < 0 and the power series for λ ( θ ) has nonzero radius then this bound is not trivial. In fact, if the X i are normal then κ n = 0 for all n ≥ 3 . Growth-Optimality against Underperformance University of California, Irvine

  6. Gambling ◮ Let W 0 be our initial wealth. ◮ We choose to bet 0 ≤ p ≤ 1 fraction of our wealth on a gamble with odds π > 1 / 2 . ◮ After T rounds our wealth is � T T � � � W p,T = W 0 R p,i = W 0 exp log R p,i i =1 i =1 where P [ R p,i = 1 + p ] = π, P [ R p,i = 1 − p ] = 1 − π ◮ The Kelly criterion says to pick p so as to maximize (1 + p ) π (1 − p ) 1 − π � � 0 ≤ p ≤ 1 E [log R p,i ] = max max 0 ≤ p ≤ 1 log Growth-Optimality against Underperformance University of California, Irvine

  7. Underperforming a benchmark Suppose we are now concerned about underperforming some benchmark rate a > 1 . � T � 1 W p,T ≤ W 0 a T � � � = P log R p,i ≤ log a P T i =1 Using large deviations we immediately have � e − θ log R p, 1 �� � � � W p,T ≤ W 0 a T � � ≤ inf θ> 0 exp θT log a + log E P � − θ �� T � �� R p, 1 = inf θ> 0 E a Growth-Optimality against Underperformance University of California, Irvine

  8. Underperforming a benchmark � − θ �� T � �� R p, 1 W p,T ≤ W 0 a T � � inf P θ> 0 E ≤ a As T grows, suppose we want to minimize our chances of underperforming the benchmark. Our goal is to pick a 0 ≤ p ≤ 1 so as to minimize �� R p, 1 � − θ � min θ> 0 E inf a 0 ≤ p ≤ 1 Suppose π = 0 . 6 and the benchmark is 1% , then this becomes � � − θ � � − θ � 1 + p � 1 − p 0 ≤ p ≤ 1 inf min 0 . 6 + 0 . 4 1 . 01 1 . 01 θ> 0 Growth-Optimality against Underperformance University of California, Irvine

  9. Kelly Criterion For π = 0 . 6 Kelly is 0 ≤ p ≤ 1 E [log R p, 1 ] = max max 0 ≤ p ≤ 1 0 . 6 log(1 + p ) + 0 . 4 log(1 − p ) � (1 + p ) 0 . 6 (1 − p ) 0 . 4 � = max 0 ≤ p ≤ 1 log which is realized when p = π − (1 − π ) = 2 π − 1 = 0 . 2 . Growth-Optimality against Underperformance University of California, Irvine

  10. Kelly Criterion � (1 + p ) 0 . 6 (1 − p ) 0 . 4 � 0 ≤ p ≤ 1 log max Growth-Optimality against Underperformance University of California, Irvine

  11. Underperforming a benchmark � − θ �� T � �� R p, 1 W p,T ≤ W 0 a T � � inf P θ> 0 E ≤ a Now suppose our goal is minimizing the probability of underperforming the benchmark 1% . We want to minimize �� R p, 1 � − θ � 0 ≤ p ≤ 1 ,θ> 0 E min a � � − θ � � − θ � 1 + p � 1 − p = min 0 . 6 + 0 . 4 1 . 01 1 . 01 0 ≤ p ≤ 1 ,θ> 0 Growth-Optimality against Underperformance University of California, Irvine

  12. Underperforming a benchmark of 1% � − θ � − θ � 1 + p � 1 − p D p,θ = 0 . 6 + 0 . 4 1 . 01 1 . 01 Growth-Optimality against Underperformance University of California, Irvine

  13. Underperforming a (smaller) benchmark of 0.1% � − θ � − θ � 1 + p � 1 − p D p,θ 0 . 6 + 0 . 4 1 . 001 1 . 001 Growth-Optimality against Underperformance University of California, Irvine

  14. Underperforming a benchmark ◮ Our goal of minimizing the asymptotic probability � − θ �� T � �� R p, 1 W p,T ≤ W 0 a T � � inf P ≤ θ> 0 E a leads us to consider a dual optimization in terms of p and θ . �� R p, 1 � − θ � 0 ≤ p ≤ 1 min min θ> 0 E a ◮ 1 + θ plays the role of the bettor’s risk aversion. It is not exogenous, but rather determined by the inner maximization. For instance, a bettor who is concerned with outperforming returns of 1% exhibits risk aversion of 1 + θ = 1 . 43 . Growth-Optimality against Underperformance University of California, Irvine

  15. Isoelastic Utility ◮ Note that our problem �� R p, 1 � − θ � 0 ≤ p ≤ 1 min min θ> 0 E a can be rephrased to appear similar to maximizing the isoelastic utility of our returns: � � 1 − γ � � R p, 1 0 ≤ p ≤ 1 max max γ> 1 E − a where γ is risk aversion. Growth-Optimality against Underperformance University of California, Irvine

  16. Risk Aversion ◮ Consider the expected utility for the Blackjack game with π = 0 . 6 and varying risk aversion 1 + θ = γ . � � � − 0 . 6(1 + p ) − θ − 0 . 4(1 − p ) − θ � − R − θ 0 ≤ p ≤ 1 E max = max p, 1 0 ≤ p ≤ 1 Growth-Optimality against Underperformance University of California, Irvine

  17. Risk Aversion ◮ If θ > 2 . 76 is a bettor’s exogenous risk aversion then a bettor considers a bet p = 10% to be unfavorable to a bet of p = 0% , regardless of their initial wealth W 0 or the number of trials T . Growth-Optimality against Underperformance University of California, Irvine

  18. Measuring Risk Aversion ◮ Barsky et al. (1997) designed a questionnaire given to thousands of individuals in person by Federal interviewers, and about 2/3 of them had relative risk aversion higher than 3 . 76 = 1 + θ . ◮ Suppose I offer you the chance to play the blackjack π = 0 . 6 game 10,000 times instantly on a computer, but if you agree you must use the strategy p = 10% . ◮ Using the large deviation bound derived above, the long term behavior hinges on � − θ �� T � �� R p, 1 � W p,T ≤ W 0 a T � P θ> 0 E inf ≤ a Growth-Optimality against Underperformance University of California, Irvine

  19. Measuring Risk Aversion ◮ The chances of underperforming an 0 . 6% benchmark are quite bad: � − θ �� 10 4 � �� R 10% , 1 � W 10% , 10 4 ≤ W 0 1 . 006 10 4 � inf P θ> 0 E ≤ 1 . 006 ≤ 0 . 998 10 4 < 10 − 8 so it is quite likely you will end up with more than W 0 × 10 24 , and all you stand to lose is W 0 . Growth-Optimality against Underperformance University of California, Irvine

  20. Measuring Risk Aversion ◮ An individual with exogenous risk of 1 + θ = 3 . 76 or greater would not want to take this bet because they are principally interested in maximizing � � � − 0 . 6(1 + p ) − θ − 0 . 4(1 − p ) − θ � − R − θ max = max 0 ≤ p ≤ 1 E p, 1 0 ≤ p ≤ 1 and the choice p = 10% is worse (according to their expected utility) than a choice of p = 0% . ◮ On the other hand, an individual hoping to beat a modest benchmark of 0 . 6% is hoping to minimize � � − θ � − θ � � 1 + p � 1 − p 0 ≤ p ≤ 1 min min 0 . 6 + 0 . 4 1 . 006 1 . 006 θ> 0 Growth-Optimality against Underperformance University of California, Irvine

  21. Measuring Risk Aversion ◮ Such an individual would be willing to take the bet. � − θ � − θ � 1 + p � 1 − p D p,θ = 0 . 6 + 0 . 4 1 . 006 1 . 006 Growth-Optimality against Underperformance University of California, Irvine

Download Presentation
Download Policy: The content available on the website is offered to you 'AS IS' for your personal information and use only. It cannot be commercialized, licensed, or distributed on other websites without prior consent from the author. To download a presentation, simply click this link. If you encounter any difficulties during the download process, it's possible that the publisher has removed the file from their server.

Recommend


More recommend