dynamic semiparametric models for expected shortfall and
play

Dynamic Semiparametric Models for Expected Shortfall (and - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

Dynamic Semiparametric Models for Expected Shortfall (and Value-at-Risk) Andrew J. Patton Johanna F. Ziegel Rui Chen Duke University University of Bern Duke University September 2017 Patton (Duke) Dynamic Models for ES (and VaR) September


  1. Dynamic Semiparametric Models for Expected Shortfall (and Value-at-Risk) Andrew J. Patton Johanna F. Ziegel Rui Chen Duke University University of Bern Duke University September 2017 Patton (Duke) Dynamic Models for ES (and VaR) September 2017 – 1 –

  2. Measures of market risk The simplest and most widely-used measure of risk is variance : h ( Y t � � t ) 2 i � 2 t � E t � 1 In the 1990s, in part prompted by Basel I and II, attention in risk management moved to Value-at-Risk: VaR t � F � 1 ( � ) ) Pr t � 1 [ Y t � VaR t ] = � t The Basel III accord pushes banks to move from Value-at-Risk towards Expected Shortfall: ES t � E t � 1 [ Y t j Y t � VaR t ] Patton (Duke) Dynamic Models for ES (and VaR) September 2017 – 2 –

  3. Why the move from VaR to ES? Academic work has highlighted some problems with VaR (see McNeil, et al. 2015 for a summary): Value-at-Risk has some positive attributes: Focuses on the left tail of returns, so more relevant for risk mgmt Easy to interpret (“the loss that is only exceeded on 5% of days”) Is well-de…ned even for fat-tailed distributions; is a robust statistic But VaR su¤ers from important drawbacks (Artzner et al. 1999, MathFin ): Not “sub-additive:” diversi…cation may make VaR look worse No information about losses beyond the VaR Expected Shortfall addresses both of these drawbacks But it is not a robust statistic, and does require moment assumptions Patton (Duke) Dynamic Models for ES (and VaR) September 2017 – 3 –

  4. Why aren’t there more models for Expected Shortfall? To answer this, consider how we estimate and model Value-at-Risk. For a given sample f Y t g T t = 1 ; VaR can be obtained as X T 1 d VaR T = arg min t = 1 L ( Y t ; v ; � ) T v where L ( y ; v ; � ) = ( 1 f y � v g � � ) ( v � y ) The loss function here is the “tick” or “lin-lin” loss function Given this loss function, it is possible to consider models like “CAViaR” (Engle and Manganelli, 2004, JBES ): X T 1 ^ � T = arg min t = 1 L ( Y t ; v ( Z t � 1 ; � ) ; � ) T � and VaR t = v ( Z t � 1 ; � ) Patton (Duke) Dynamic Models for ES (and VaR) September 2017 – 4 –

  5. The “lin-lin” loss function Lin-lin loss functions 3 alpha=0.05 alpha=0.20 2.5 alpha=0.50 (abs value) 2 s s 1.5 o L 1 0.5 0 -3 -2 -1 0 1 2 3 Forecast Patton (Duke) Dynamic Models for ES (and VaR) September 2017 – 5 –

  6. Why aren’t there more models for Expected Shortfall? Given an estimator of VaR, sample Expected Shortfall can be computed as: X T 1 c ES T = t = 1 Y t 1 f Y t � VaR t g � T Patton (Duke) Dynamic Models for ES (and VaR) September 2017 – 6 –

  7. Why aren’t there more models for Expected Shortfall? Given an estimator of VaR, sample Expected Shortfall can be computed as: X T 1 c ES T = t = 1 Y t 1 f Y t � VaR t g � T But there does not exist an objective function such that ES is the solution: X T 1 t = 1 L � ( Y t ; e ; � ) c @ L � s.t. ES T = arg min T e Patton (Duke) Dynamic Models for ES (and VaR) September 2017 – 6 –

  8. Why aren’t there more models for Expected Shortfall? Given an estimator of VaR, sample Expected Shortfall can be computed as: X T 1 c ES T = t = 1 Y t 1 f Y t � VaR t g � T But there does not exist an objective function such that ES is the solution: X T 1 t = 1 L � ( Y t ; e ; � ) c @ L � s.t. ES T = arg min T e Expected Shortfall is “ non-elicitable ” (Gneiting 2011, JASA ). This explains, perhaps, the lack of models for Expected Shortfall: Patton (Duke) Dynamic Models for ES (and VaR) September 2017 – 6 –

  9. Why aren’t there more models for Expected Shortfall? Given an estimator of VaR, sample Expected Shortfall can be computed as: X T 1 c ES T = t = 1 Y t 1 f Y t � VaR t g � T But there does not exist an objective function such that ES is the solution: X T 1 t = 1 L � ( Y t ; e ; � ) c @ L � s.t. ES T = arg min T e Expected Shortfall is “ non-elicitable ” (Gneiting 2011, JASA ). This explains, perhaps, the lack of models for Expected Shortfall: F We exploit recent results in statistics and decision theory which shows that while ES is not elicitable, it is jointly elicitable with Value-at-Risk. Patton (Duke) Dynamic Models for ES (and VaR) September 2017 – 6 –

  10. Related literature A lot of work has been done on models for risk management, mostly VaR: McNeil, Frey and Embrechts (2015, Quantitative Risk Mgmt ) Daníelsson (2011, Financial Risk Forecasting ) Komunjer (2010, Handbook of Economic Forecasting ) This paper is closest to Engle and Manganelli (2004, JBES ) who propose time series models for conditional quantiles, and establish conditions for estimation and inference We extend their paper to consider ES (jointly with VaR) We draw on two distinct recent advances in the literature: Statistical decision theory: Fissler and Ziegel (2016, AoS) Parameter-driven time series models: Creal, Koopman and Lucas (2013, JAE ) Patton (Duke) Dynamic Models for ES (and VaR) September 2017 – 7 –

  11. Outline 1 Motivation and introduction 2 Estimating Expected Shortfall (and Value-at-Risk) The Fissler-Ziegel loss function Dynamic models for VaR and ES 3 Inference methods Assumptions and main results Simulation study of …nite-sample properties 4 Results for four international equity indices In-sample parameter estimates and hypothesis tests Out-of-sample forecast comparisons 5 Summary and conclusion Patton (Duke) Dynamic Models for ES (and VaR) September 2017 – 8 –

  12. Joint estimation of VaR and Expected Shortfall Fissler and Ziegel (2016, AoS) show that while ES is not elicitable, it is jointly elicitable with VaR, using the class of “FZ” loss functions. We will use a homogeneous of degree zero FZ loss function, as for the values of � of interest we know ES t < 0 : There is only one such FZ loss: L FZ 0 ( Y ; v ; e ; � ) = � 1 � e 1 f Y � v g ( v � Y ) � 1 e ( e � v ) + log ( � e ) where Y is the (future) return, v is the VaR forecast, and e is the ES forecast. This loss function yields loss function di¤erences (between two competing sets of VaR and ES forecasts) thare homogeneous of degree zero. Minimizing this loss function yields VaR and ES: [ VaR t ; ES t ] = arg min ( v ; e ) E t � 1 [ L FZ 0 ( Y t ; v ; e ; � )] Patton (Duke) Dynamic Models for ES (and VaR) September 2017 – 9 –

  13. The FZ0 loss function The implied VaR loss is the familiar “tick” loss function; the implied ES loss resembles “QLIKE” FZ loss as a fn of VaR FZ loss as a fn of ES 3 3 2.5 2.5 2 2 Loss Loss 1.5 1.5 1 1 0.5 0.5 0 0 -4 -3 -2 -1 0 -4 -3 -2 -1 0 VaR forecast ES forecast Patton (Duke) Dynamic Models for ES (and VaR) September 2017 – 10 –

  14. The expected FZ0 loss function for a N(0,1) target variable. Contours are convex. Expected FZ0 loss for a standard Normal variable 0 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 -0.5 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 -1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 0.75 0.75 0.75 0.75 0.75 0.75 0.75 0.75 0.75 0.75 0.75 0.75 -1.5 VaR -2 -2.5 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 -3 -3.5 -4 -4 -3.5 -3 -2.5 -2 -1.5 -1 -0.5 0 ES Patton (Duke) Dynamic Models for ES (and VaR) September 2017 – 11 –

  15. Dynamic models for ES and VaR With a loss function available, it is possible to consider dynamic models for ES and VaR: VaR t = v ( Z t � 1 ; � ) ES t = e ( Z t � 1 ; � ) The parameters of this model can then be obtained as: X T 1 ^ � T = arg min t = 1 L ( Y t ; v ( Z t � 1 ; � ) ; e ( Z t � 1 ; � )) T � We propose some new models for ES (and VaR), drawing on recent research, and then provide theory for estimation and inference for these models. Patton (Duke) Dynamic Models for ES (and VaR) September 2017 – 12 –

  16. GAS models for dynamic ES and VaR I Creal et al. (2013, JAE ) proposed “generalized autoregressive score” models for time-varying density models: Y t jF t � 1 s F ( � t ) @ log f ( y t � 1 ; � t � 1 ) � t = w + B � � t � 1 + A � S t � 1 @ � Using the score ( @ log f =@ � ) as the “forcing variable” enables them to nest many existing models, including ARMA and GARCH models. The “scale” matrix, S t � 1 , is often set to the inverse Hessian. This choice of forcing variable can be motivated as the Newton-Raphson step in a numerical optimization algorithm. Patton (Duke) Dynamic Models for ES (and VaR) September 2017 – 13 –

  17. GAS models for dynamic ES and VaR II We adopt this modeling approach, and apply it to our M-estimation problem. Consider the following GAS(1,1) speci…cation for VaR and ES: � v t + 1 � � v t � � @ 2 E t � 1 [ L ( Y t ; v t ; e t )] � � 1 @ L ( Y t ; v t ; e t ) = w + B + A @ ( ve ) @ ( ve ) 0 e t + 1 e t @ ( ve ) � v t � 1 � � � v ; t � 1 � = w + B + A e t � 1 � e ; t � 1 where the “forcing variables” are given by = � v t ( 1 f Y t � v t g � � ) � v ; t � 1 � � e ; t = � � 1 f Y t � v t g Y t � e t Patton (Duke) Dynamic Models for ES (and VaR) September 2017 – 14 –

Download Presentation
Download Policy: The content available on the website is offered to you 'AS IS' for your personal information and use only. It cannot be commercialized, licensed, or distributed on other websites without prior consent from the author. To download a presentation, simply click this link. If you encounter any difficulties during the download process, it's possible that the publisher has removed the file from their server.

Recommend


More recommend