chapter 3 price discrimination
play

Chapter 3: Price Discrimination A1. The goods produced by the - PDF document

Chapter 3: Price Discrimination A1. The goods produced by the monopolist are given. Relax A2. Price discrimination (PD). PD if 2 units of the same physical good are sold at different prices to the same or to different consumers. Examples:


  1. Chapter 3: Price Discrimination A1. The goods produced by the monopolist are given. Relax A2. Price discrimination (PD). PD if 2 units of the same physical good are sold at different prices to the same or to different consumers. Examples: discount, airline tickets... • PD is linked to the possibility of arbitrage – transferability of the commodity → reduces PD – transferability of demand → increases PD 3 kinds of PD (Pigou (1920)) 1. First-degree PD - Perfect PD; – need to have all information 2. Second-degree PD – self-selecting device 3. Third-degree PD – signal (age, occupation,...) 1

  2. 1 First Degree Price Discrimination • Discrete case – Identical consumers – unit demand – v : consumer’s willingness to pay. – A monopolist charges p = v in order to extract the entire surplus. • Continuous case – n identical consumers – same demand function q i = D ( p ) n – Total demand: q = D ( p ) – Linear pricing schedule T ( q ) = pq gives a pro fi t p m D ( p m ) − C ( D ( p m )) – The monopolist can increase his pro fi t if he proposes a two-part tariff : T ( q ) = A + pq. – The monopolist sets the competitive price p c . – The surplus of the consumers is Z q c S c = ( p ( q ) − p c ) dq 0 2

  3. – And each consumer must pay a fi xed premium A = S c n – The monopolist proposes an af fi ne (nonlinear) pricing schedule ( two part tariff ): ( p c q + S c n if q > 0 T ( q ) = if q = 0 0 – The pro fi t of the monopolist is Π = S c + p c q − C ( q c ) • Non identical consumers: they have different demand curves. – The optimal pricing scheme is p = MC – and each consumer pays a personalized fi xed premium S c i ( p c ) . • BUT problem of information . • and of arbitrage.... 3

  4. 2 Third Degree PD • Single product, total cost C ( q ) • m groups of consumers (age, sex, occupation,...). • Each group has a different demand function. • Monopolist knows these demand functions. • No arbitrage between groups, but no PD within a group. • Linear tariff: { p 1 , ..., p i , ..., p m } • Quantities demanded: { q 1 = D 1 ( p 1 ) , ..., q i = D i ( p i ) , ..., q m = D m ( p m ) } • Aggregate demand is q = P m i =1 D i ( p i ) • Monopolist chooses prices that maximize m m X X D i ( p i ) p i − C ( D i ( p i )) i =1 i =1 • Remember: multiproduct pricing with independent demands and separable costs! ⇒ $ i ≡ p i − C 0 ( . ) = 1 p i ε i 4

  5. Result 1 Optimal pricing implies that the monopolist should charge more in markets with the lower elasticity. Example: Students vs non-students... • What can we say in terms of welfare ? Does PD increase or decrease welfare? • What would happen if the monopolist were forced to charge the same price? Uniform price ( p ) Result 2 Consumers with high elastic demand (resp. low) prefer discrimination (resp. uniform pricing). • Marginal cost: c • Under PD: – p i in market i , D i ( p i ) = q i – Aggregate CS and pro fi t are m X CS D = S i ( p i ) i =1 X m Π m D = ( p i − c ) q i i =1 5

  6. • PD is prohibited – uniform price p , and thus D i ( p ) = q i – Aggregate CS and pro fi t are X m CS No = S i ( p ) i =1 X m Π m No = ( p − c ) q i i =1 • Difference in total welfare ∆ W = CS D − CS No + Π m D − Π m No X m X m X m ∆ W = ( S i ( p i ) − S i ( p )) + ( p i − c ) q i − ( p − c ) q i i =1 i =1 i =1 • Thus – if ∆ W > 0 , welfare is higher under PD, – if ∆ W < 0 , welfare is lower under PD. 6

  7. • Upper and lower bounds for ∆ W (to show) X m (1) ∆ W ≥ ( p i − c )( q i − q i ) i =1 m X (2) ∆ W ≤ ( p − c ) ( q i − q i ) i =1 • PD reduces welfare if it does not increase total output – from equation (2), if P m i =1 q i = P m i =1 q i then ∆ W ≤ 0 . • To be preferred socially, PD must raise total output. • Case of linear demand functions: q i = a i − b i p for i • Assume that a i > b i c for any i . • Under PD – Monopolist chooses p i that solves Max ( p i − c )( a i − b i p i ) 7

  8. and thus p i = a i + cb i 2 b i q i = a i − cb i 2 – Thus the sum of the output is X m X m a i − cb i q i = 2 i =1 i =1 • Under uniform pricing – All markets are served at the optimum. – Monopolist chooses p that solves X m X m Max ( p − c )( a i − p b i ) i =1 i =1 and thus P m i =1 a i + c P m i =1 b i 2 P m p = i =1 b i P m i =1 a i − c P m X m i =1 b i q i = 2 i =1 8

  9. • And thus, same total output m m m X X X q i = q i ⇒ ( q i − q i ) = 0 i =1 i =1 i =1 and according to equation (2) ∆ W ≤ 0 , welfare is lower under PD. • This outcome depends on the assumption: all markets are served under uniform pricing (+ linear demand). • Welfare conclusion can be reversed.... – 2 markets, i.e. m = 2 – under uniform pricing, second market is not served. – PD: p m 1 , p m 2 , q m 1 , q m 2 . – Uniform pricing: p = p m 1 , q 1 = q m 1 , q 2 = 0 , and thus X m ( q i − q i ) = q m 1 − q m 1 + q m 2 − 0 = q m 2 > 0 i =1 m X ( p i − c )( q i − q i ) = ( p m 1 − c ) × 0 + ( p m 2 − c ) q m 2 > 0 i =1 and from equation (1) ∆ W ≥ 0 . – In this case: PD increases welfare. – PD leads to Pareto improvement: monopolist makes more pro fi t, and CS increases in market 2. 9

  10. • Ambiguous effects of PD on welfare . Trade-off between – loss of consumers in low-elasticity markets – gain of consumers in high-elasticity markets. • If PD is prohibited: it can conduct to closure of market.... 10

  11. 3 Second Degree PD • Heterogeneous consumers • Monopolist knows they are heterogeneous. • Monopolist will offer a menu of bundles to choose from. • Personal arbitrage can happen: self selection or incentive constraints. 3.1 Two Part Tariffs • T ( q ) = A + pq . • Menu of bundles { T, q } • Consumers’ preferences are ( θ V ( q ) − T if they pay T and consume q units u = otherwise 0 where – V (0) = 0 , V 0 ( q ) > 0 , V 00 ( q ) < 0 . – θ taste parameter. • 2 groups of consumers: – a proportion λ of consumers with parameter taste θ 1 ; – a proportion (1 − λ ) with parameter taste θ 2 . 11

  12. • Marginal cost c, • Assumption: – θ 2 > θ 1 > c , – V ( q ) = 1 − (1 − q ) 2 and thus V 0 ( q ) = (1 − q ) > 0 2 • What is the demand function of a consumer θ i facing a price p ? – Consumer solves Max { θ i V ( q ) − pq } q – Thus demand function is D i ( p ) = 1 − p θ i – Aggregate demand function D ( p ) = λ D 1 ( p ) + (1 − λ ) D 2 ( p ) D ( p ) = 1 − p ( λ + 1 − λ ) = 1 − p θ 1 θ 2 θ where 1 θ = λ θ 1 + 1 − λ θ 2 is the “harmonic mean”. 12

  13. – Net consumers surplus is S i ( p ) = θ i V ( D i ( p )) − pD i ( p ) S i ( p ) = ( θ i − p ) 2 2 θ i 3.1.1 Perfect Price Discrimination • If the monopolist can observe θ i • He charges p 1 = c per unit plus a fi xed premium A i = S i ( c ) = ( θ i − p 1 ) 2 2 θ i where ∂ A i ∂θ i > 0 , and thus A 2 > A 1 . • Pro fi t of the monopolist is Π 1 = λ ( θ 1 − p 1 ) 2 + (1 − λ )( θ 2 − p 1 ) 2 2 θ 1 2 θ 2 • If the monopolist cannot observe θ i : arbitrage problem. High demand consumers have an incentive to claim they are low demand type. 13

  14. 3.1.2 Monopoly Pricing • Monopolist charges a fully linear tariff T ( q ) = pq • Assumption: monopolist serves the two types of consumers (Formally c + θ 2 ≤ θ 1 and λ not too small). 2 • Monopolist chooses p that solves Max ( p − c ) D ( p ) p and thus p 2 = c + θ 2 and the monopolist pro fi t is Π 2 = ( θ − c ) 2 4 θ 3.1.3 Two-part tariff • Assumption: the monopolist serves the two-types of consumers. • To make them buy: A = S 1 ( p ) • Monopolist chooses p that solves Max { S 1 ( p ) + ( p − c ) D ( p ) } p 14

  15. and thus the price is c p 3 = 2 − θ θ 1 and the pro fi t is Π 3 = S 1 ( p 3 ) + ( p 3 − c ) D ( p 3 ) 3.1.4 Comparison • Pro fi ts Π 1 ≥ Π 3 ≥ Π 2 – Maximum pro fi t under perfect PD – Monopolist can always duplicate a linear tariff with a two-part tariff. • Prices p 1 = c < p 3 < p 2 = p m – A lower price induces less monopoly pro fi t but higher fi xed part. • Welfare W ( p 3 ) > W ( p 2 ) as W ( p ) is decreasing with p . 15

  16. W ( p ) = λ [ S g 1 ( p ) − cD 1 ( p )] + (1 − λ )[ S g 2 ( p ) − cD 2 ( p )] S g i ( p ) = S i ( p ) + pD i ( p ) S g i ( p ) = θ i V ( D i ( p )) − pD i ( p ) + pD i ( p ) S g i ( p ) = θ i V ( D i ( p )) Thus ∂ [ S g 1 ( p ) − cD 1 ( p )] = θ i V 0 ( p ) D 0 i ( p ) − cD 0 i ( p ) ∂ p = − p + c ≤ 0 θ i θ i – Because p 3 < p 2 , consumers under two part tariff consume more (reduces distortion) – And Π 3 ≥ Π 2 • Graph • Using a graph, show that for any linear tariff T ( q ) = pq with p > c , there exists a two-part tariff e pq + e T ( q ) = e A such that if consumers are offered the choice between T and e T , both types of consumers and the fi rm are made better off (exercise 3.4). 16

Download Presentation
Download Policy: The content available on the website is offered to you 'AS IS' for your personal information and use only. It cannot be commercialized, licensed, or distributed on other websites without prior consent from the author. To download a presentation, simply click this link. If you encounter any difficulties during the download process, it's possible that the publisher has removed the file from their server.

Recommend


More recommend