asset pricing
play

Asset Pricing Ljungqvist / Sargent Chapter 8, 13 Kjetil - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

Asset Pricing Ljungqvist / Sargent Chapter 8, 13 Kjetil Storesletten University of Oslo 1 Motivation Facts: Real Returns 50 40 30 20 10 0 -10 -20 -30 -40 Stock T Bill -50 1930 1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 Real stock


  1. Asset Pricing Ljungqvist / Sargent Chapter 8, 13 Kjetil Storesletten University of Oslo

  2. 1 Motivation Facts: Real Returns 50 40 30 20 10 0 -10 -20 -30 -40 Stock T Bill -50 1930 1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 Real stock and bond returns 1927-2002 Bond (Stock-Bond) Mean annual % return 1.1 7.5 Standard Deviation 4.4 20.8 1 MOTIVATION 2

  3. Real value of a dollar invested in 1927 3 10 stock bond 2 10 1 10 0 10 -1 10 1920 1930 1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 ¨ 1 MOTIVATION 3

  4. • Assets are used to shift consumption between periods. • Some assets are not perfectly safe . Hence, the agent experiences some uncer- tainty about future payoffs, which results in uncertainty about future levels of consumption . • Based on this thought, agents will price assets not only depending on its return compared to the risk-free rate, but also depending on each agent’s willingness to take risk (willingness to forego some consumption smoothing for a higher absolute level of consumption). 1 MOTIVATION 4

  5. 2 Asset Euler Equations Agent’s Maximization Problem: • Agents maximize expected lifetime utility: ∞ � β j u ( c t + j ) , E t 0 < β < 1 . (2.1) j =0 • Individuals can hold bonds and equity. Assets can be sold short , but borrowing constraints work on both equity and fixed-income holdings. • Notation: – L t : Bond holdings – N t : Equity holdings – Borrowing constraints: L t ≥ − b L , N t ≥ − b N . – Risk-free real gross interest rate: R t , measured in units of time t + 1 consumption good per time t consumption good. 2 ASSET EULER EQUATIONS 5

  6. • Budget constraint: − 1 L t + p t N t ≤ A t . c t + R t (2.2) • Next period’s wealth: A t +1 = L t + ( p t +1 + y t +1 ) N t (2.3) y t +1 : stochastic dividend income • Hence, the agent’s maximization problem is a dynamic programming problem. 2 ASSET EULER EQUATIONS 6

  7. Euler Equations: • At interior solutions, the Euler equations are − 1 = E t βu ′ ( c t +1 ) , u ′ ( c t ) R t u ′ ( c t ) p t = E t β ( y t +1 + p t +1 ) u ′ ( c t +1 ) . (2.4) • Transversality conditions: k →∞ E t β k u ′ ( c t + k ) R − 1 k →∞ E t β k u ′ ( c t + k ) p t + k N t + k = 0 . lim t + k L t + k = 0 , lim (2.5) • If any of the transversality conditions (2.5) would be positive, the agent would be overaccumulating assets. This is the analogous condition to a finite horizon model where the agent will not die with positive asset holdings. • Were they negative, the agent would be given credit he cannot pay up - a contract that no one would enter. 2 ASSET EULER EQUATIONS 7

  8. 3 Martingale Theories of Consumption and Stock Prices • Assume that the risk-free interest rate is constant ( R t = R > 1). Thus: E t u ′ ( c t +1 ) = ( βR ) − 1 u ′ ( c t ) . Hence, u ′ ( c ) follows a univariate linear first-order Markov process. • Rearranging the Euler equation yields: E t β ( y t +1 + p t +1 ) u ′ ( c t +1 ) u ′ ( c t ) = p t . (3.1) • The left-hand side of (3.1) is the expected value of a product of two random variables. Apply E t ( xz ) = E t xE t z + cov ( x, z ): � � u ′ ( c t +1 ) ( y t +1 + p t +1 ) , u ′ ( c t +1 ) βE t ( y t +1 + p t +1 ) E t u ′ ( c t ) + βcov t = p t (3.2) u ′ ( c t ) 3 MARTINGALE THEORIES OF CONSUMPTION AND STOCK PRICES 8

  9. • Can it be the case that p t = βE t ( y t +1 + p t +1 )? Unlikely to be satisfied for general utility functions! Then u ′ ( c t ) • One obvious example where it fits is risk-neutrality of agents. becomes independent of c t , E t u ′ ( c t +1 ) /u ′ ( c t ) = 1, and � � ( y t +1 + p t +1 ) , u ′ ( c t +1 ) cov t = 0 . u ′ ( c t ) • Stock prices then suffice E t β ( y t +1 + p t +1 ) = p t . (3.3) • Adjusted for dividends and discounting, the share price follows a first-order univariate Markov process and no other variables Granger cause the share price. 3 MARTINGALE THEORIES OF CONSUMPTION AND STOCK PRICES 9

  10. • The stochastic difference equation (3.3) in that case has the class of solutions ∞ � 1 � t � β j y t + j p t = E t + ξ t , (3.4) β j =1 � �� � � �� � bubbleterm expecteddiscounted futuredividends where ξ t is any random process that obeys E t ξ t +1 = ξ t . The ‘bubble term’ must be zero in equilibrium. 3 MARTINGALE THEORIES OF CONSUMPTION AND STOCK PRICES 10

  11. 4 Equilibrium Asset Pricing Lucas’ breakthrough on asset pricing (Econometrica 1978) • So-called ‘Lucas’ Tree Model’. Trees are durable, dividends (fruits) are not. Each agent owns one tree at time 0. • Dividend follows a Markov process and is the only state variable of the economy. • An asset-pricing model has the following features: 1. It is a dynamic economy. 2. Specified preferences, technology and endowments. 3. Equilibrium is competitive 4 EQUILIBRIUM ASSET PRICING 11

  12. • Equilibrium intertemporal consumption allocation then satisfies: E t u ′ ( c t +1 ) = ( βR ) − 1 u ′ ( c t ) . � � βu ′ ( c t +1 ) E t u ′ ( c t ) · ( y t +1 + p t +1 ) = p t . (4.1) • Equate consumption that appears in the Euler equation to the equilibrium consumption derived in the first step. This procedure will give the asset price at t as a function of the state of the economy at t . u ′ ( y t ) R − 1 = E t βu ′ ( y t +1 ) , t u ′ ( y t ) p t = E t β ( y t +1 + p t +1 ) u ′ ( y t +1 ) . 4 EQUILIBRIUM ASSET PRICING 12

  13. 5 Stock Prices without Bubbles • Using recursions on the previous equation and the law of iterated expectations ( E t E t +1 ( · ) = E t ( · )), we arrive at the equilibrium share price: ∞ � u ′ ( y t ) p t = E t β j u ′ ( y t + j ) y t + j + E t lim k →∞ β k u ′ ( y t + k ) p t + k . (5.1) j =1 • Market clearing implies that the last term must be zero (agents must be willing to hold their trees forever). • Would it be positive, then the marginal utility from selling shares, u ′ ( y t ) p t , exceeds the marginal utility loss of holding the asset forever and consuming the � ∞ j =1 β j u ′ ( y t + j ) y t + j . Then, everybody would future stream of dividends, E t like to sell shares and asset prices would immediately be driven down. • The same arguments holds vice versa: If the term is negative, all agents would like to purchase more shares and the price would soar. 5 STOCK PRICES WITHOUT BUBBLES 13

  14. • Hence, in equilibrium, the price must satisfy ∞ β j u ′ ( y t + j ) � p t = E t u ′ ( y t ) y t + j , (5.2) j =1 which is a generalization of equation (3.4). 5 STOCK PRICES WITHOUT BUBBLES 14

  15. Consider a simple example: • u ( c ) = log ( c ) • y t is a random walk with constant drfit g : log y t = log y t − 1 + g + ε t • Consider equation (5.2); ∞ ∞ β j y t β � � β j = p t = E t y t + j = y t 1 − βy t y t + j j =1 j =1 – Constant price-dividend ratio p t /y t – Asset price is independent of expected growth rate g 5 STOCK PRICES WITHOUT BUBBLES 15

  16. 6 The Term Structure of Interest Rates Consider there are two zero-bonds with maturity of 1 and 2 years, respectively. The law of motion for wealth is then c t + R − 1 1 t L 1 t + R − 1 2 t L 2 t + p t N t ≤ A t , (6.1) A t +1 = L 1 t + R − 1 1 t +1 L 2 t + ( p t +1 + y t +1 ) N t . (6.2) Hence the Bellman equation for this problem is: � u [ A t − R − 1 1 t L 1 t − R − 1 v ( A t , s t ) = max 2 t L 2 t − p ( s t ) N t ] L 1 t ,L 2 t ,N t � + βE t v ( L 1 t + R − 1 t +1 L 2 t + [ p ( s t +1 ) + y t +1 ] N t , s t +1 ) 6 THE TERM STRUCTURE OF INTEREST RATES 16

  17. The first-order conditions are: u ′ ( c t ) R − 1 1 t = βE t v 1 ( A t +1 , s t +1 ) , (6.3) � � u ′ ( c t ) R − 1 v 1 ( A t +1 , s t +1 ) R − 1 2 t = βE t . (6.4) 1 t +1 Applying the envelope theorem and setting c t = y t = s t , the equilibrium rates of return equal � u ′ ( s t +1 ) � R − 1 ≡ R 1 ( s t ) − 1 1 t = βE t (6.5) u ′ ( s t ) � u ′ ( s t +1 ) � � u ′ ( s t +2 ) � R − 1 u ′ ( s t ) R − 1 ≡ β 2 E t ≡ R 2 ( s t ) − 1 2 t = βE t (6.6) 1+1 u ′ ( s t ) 6 THE TERM STRUCTURE OF INTEREST RATES 17

  18. Because of the Markov assumptions, interest rates can be written as time-invariant functions of the economy’s current state s t . The general expression of (6.6) is as follows: � u ′ ( s t + j ) � R − 1 jt = β j E t . (6.7) u ′ ( s t ) This rate is not annualized and smaller than 1. If we invert and exponentiate with ( · ) 1 /j , we get the yield to maturity of a zero coupon bond: jt = β − 1 � u ′ ( s t )[ E t u ′ ( s t + j )] − 1 � 1 /j R jt = R 1 /j ˜ (6.8) If dividends are i.i.d. over time, the yields to maturity for a j-period and a k-period bond are then related as follows: u ′ ( s t )[ Eu ′ ( s )] − 1 � k − j � R jt = ˜ ˜ kj R kt 6 THE TERM STRUCTURE OF INTEREST RATES 18

Download Presentation
Download Policy: The content available on the website is offered to you 'AS IS' for your personal information and use only. It cannot be commercialized, licensed, or distributed on other websites without prior consent from the author. To download a presentation, simply click this link. If you encounter any difficulties during the download process, it's possible that the publisher has removed the file from their server.

Recommend


More recommend