an optimal stopping mean field game of resource sharing
play

An optimal stopping mean-field game of resource sharing Geraldine - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

An optimal stopping mean-field game of resource sharing Geraldine Bouveret 1 Roxana Dumitrescu 2 Peter Tankov 3 1 Oxford University 2 Kings College London 3 CRESTENSAE IMSFIPS Workshop London, September 10, 2018 Peter Tankov (ENSAE) A


  1. An optimal stopping mean-field game of resource sharing Geraldine Bouveret 1 Roxana Dumitrescu 2 Peter Tankov 3 1 Oxford University 2 King’s College London 3 CREST–ENSAE IMS–FIPS Workshop London, September 10, 2018 Peter Tankov (ENSAE) A mean-field game of resource sharing June 25–29, 2018 1 / 31

  2. Introduction Outline 1 Introduction 2 Mean-field games 3 MFG of optimal stopping 4 MFG of optimal stopping: the relaxed control approach 5 Back to the game of resource sharing Peter Tankov (ENSAE) A mean-field game of resource sharing June 25–29, 2018 2 / 31

  3. Introduction How do economic agents adapt to climate change? • Water security is one of the most tangible and fastest-growing social, political and economic challenges faced today • The coal industry is an important consumer of freshwater resources and is responsible for 7% of all water withdrawal globally • Cooling power plants are responsible for the greatest demand in fresh water Peter Tankov (ENSAE) A mean-field game of resource sharing June 25–29, 2018 3 / 31

  4. Introduction A model for producers competing for a scarce resource • Consider N producers sharing a resource whose supply per unit of time is limited (e.g., fresh water) and denoted by � Z t ; Peter Tankov (ENSAE) A mean-field game of resource sharing June 25–29, 2018 4 / 31

  5. Introduction A model for producers competing for a scarce resource • Consider N producers sharing a resource whose supply per unit of time is limited (e.g., fresh water) and denoted by � Z t ; • Each producer initially uses technology 1 requiring fresh water, and can switch to technology 2 (not using water) at some future date τ i ; Peter Tankov (ENSAE) A mean-field game of resource sharing June 25–29, 2018 4 / 31

  6. Introduction A model for producers competing for a scarce resource • Consider N producers sharing a resource whose supply per unit of time is limited (e.g., fresh water) and denoted by � Z t ; • Each producer initially uses technology 1 requiring fresh water, and can switch to technology 2 (not using water) at some future date τ i ; • Each producer faces demand level M i t and can produce up to M i t if the water supply allows: • With technology 1, one unit of water is required to produce one unit of good; • With technology 2, no water is required. Peter Tankov (ENSAE) A mean-field game of resource sharing June 25–29, 2018 4 / 31

  7. Introduction A model for producers competing for a scarce resource • Consider N producers sharing a resource whose supply per unit of time is limited (e.g., fresh water) and denoted by � Z t ; • Each producer initially uses technology 1 requiring fresh water, and can switch to technology 2 (not using water) at some future date τ i ; • Each producer faces demand level M i t and can produce up to M i t if the water supply allows: • With technology 1, one unit of water is required to produce one unit of good; • With technology 2, no water is required. • In case of shortage of water, the available supply is shared among producers according to their demand levels. Peter Tankov (ENSAE) A mean-field game of resource sharing June 25–29, 2018 4 / 31

  8. Introduction A model for producers competing for a scarce resource • The demand of i -th producer follows the dynamics dM i t = µ dt + σ dW i M i 0 = m i . t , M i t where W 1 , . . . , W N are independent Brownian motions. Peter Tankov (ENSAE) A mean-field game of resource sharing June 25–29, 2018 5 / 31

  9. Introduction A model for producers competing for a scarce resource • The demand of i -th producer follows the dynamics dM i t = µ dt + σ dW i M i 0 = m i . t , M i t where W 1 , . . . , W N are independent Brownian motions. • With technology 2, the output is M i t and with technology 1 the output is   N �   M i if � M j  t , Z t ≥ t 1 τ j > t   i =1 Q i t =  �  Z t   M i otherwise .  � N  t j =1 M j t 1 τ j > t ⇒ Q i t = ω N t M i t , where ω N t is the proportion of demand which may be satisfied � Z t ω N t = ∧ 1 . � N j =1 M j t 1 τ j > t Peter Tankov (ENSAE) A mean-field game of resource sharing June 25–29, 2018 5 / 31

  10. Introduction Cost function of producers The cost function of the producer is given by � τ i � τ i � ∞ e − ρ t ˆ e − ρ t ˜ e − ρ t pQ i t ) dt − e − ρτ i K + p ( M i t − Q i pM i t dt − t dt 0 0 τ i � τ i � τ i � ∞ e − ρ t ˆ e − ρ t ˜ e − ρ t p ω N t M i p (1 − ω N t ) M i t dt − e − ρτ i K + pM i = t dt − t dt 0 0 τ i where we assume that ρ > µ . p is the gain from producing with technology 1; p is the penalty paid for not meeting the demand; ˆ K is the cost of switching the technology; p is the gain from producing with technology 2. ˜ Peter Tankov (ENSAE) A mean-field game of resource sharing June 25–29, 2018 6 / 31

  11. Mean-field games Outline 1 Introduction 2 Mean-field games 3 MFG of optimal stopping 4 MFG of optimal stopping: the relaxed control approach 5 Back to the game of resource sharing Peter Tankov (ENSAE) A mean-field game of resource sharing June 25–29, 2018 7 / 31

  12. Mean-field games Mean-field games Introduced by Lasry and Lions (2006,2007) and Huang, Caines and Malham´ e (2006) to describe large-population games with symmetric interactions. t ∈ R d by taking an action α i • Each player controls its state X i t ∈ A ⊂ R k : µ N − 1 µ N − 1 dX i t = b ( t , X i , α i t ) dt + σ ( t , X i , α i t ) dW i t , ¯ t , ¯ t , X − i X − i t t W i are independent and ¯ µ N − 1 is the empirical distribution of other players. X − i t Peter Tankov (ENSAE) A mean-field game of resource sharing June 25–29, 2018 8 / 31

  13. Mean-field games Mean-field games Introduced by Lasry and Lions (2006,2007) and Huang, Caines and Malham´ e (2006) to describe large-population games with symmetric interactions. t ∈ R d by taking an action α i • Each player controls its state X i t ∈ A ⊂ R k : µ N − 1 µ N − 1 dX i t = b ( t , X i , α i t ) dt + σ ( t , X i , α i t ) dW i t , ¯ t , ¯ t , X − i X − i t t W i are independent and ¯ µ N − 1 is the empirical distribution of other players. X − i t • Each player minimises the cost �� T � J i ( α f ( t , X i µ N − 1 , α i t ) dt + g ( X i µ N − 1 α α ) = E t , ¯ T , ¯ T ) , X − i X − i t 0 α ∈ A N : ∀ i , ∀ α i ∈ A , J i (ˆ α − i ). α ) ≤ J i ( α i , ˆ • We look for a Nash equilibrium: ˆ α α α α α α Peter Tankov (ENSAE) A mean-field game of resource sharing June 25–29, 2018 8 / 31

  14. Mean-field games Mean-field games µ N − 1 As N → ∞ , it is natural to assume that ¯ converges to a deterministic X − i t distribution; Nash equilibrium is described as follows (Carmona and Delarue ’17): • The representative player controls its state X α depending on the deterministic flow ( µ t ) 0 ≤ t ≤ T : dX α t = b ( t , X α t , µ t , α t ) dt + σ ( t , X α t , µ t , α t ) dW t . • It minimises the cost �� T � α ∈ A J µ ( α ) , J µ ( α ) = E f ( t , X α t , µ t , α t ) dt + g ( X α inf T , µ T ) ( ∗ ) 0 Peter Tankov (ENSAE) A mean-field game of resource sharing June 25–29, 2018 9 / 31

  15. Mean-field games Mean-field games µ N − 1 As N → ∞ , it is natural to assume that ¯ converges to a deterministic X − i t distribution; Nash equilibrium is described as follows (Carmona and Delarue ’17): • The representative player controls its state X α depending on the deterministic flow ( µ t ) 0 ≤ t ≤ T : dX α t = b ( t , X α t , µ t , α t ) dt + σ ( t , X α t , µ t , α t ) dW t . • It minimises the cost �� T � α ∈ A J µ ( α ) , J µ ( α ) = E f ( t , X α t , µ t , α t ) dt + g ( X α inf T , µ T ) ( ∗ ) 0 X µ is • We look for a flow ( µ t ) 0 ≤ t ≤ T such that L ( ˆ t ) = µ t , t ∈ [0 , T ], where ˆ X µ the solution to ( ∗ ). Peter Tankov (ENSAE) A mean-field game of resource sharing June 25–29, 2018 9 / 31

  16. Mean-field games The analytic approach The stochastic control problem is characterized as the solution to a HJB equation � � f ( t , x , µ t , α ) + b ( t , x , µ t , α ) ∂ x V + 1 2 σ 2 ( t , x , µ t , α ) ∂ 2 ∂ t V + max xx V = 0 α with the terminal condition V ( T , x ) = g ( x , µ T ). The flow of densities solves the Fokker-Planck equation ∂ t µ t − 1 2 ∂ 2 xx ( σ 2 ( t , x , µ t , ˆ α t ) µ t ) + ∂ x ( b ( t , x , µ t , ˆ α t ) µ t ) = 0 , with the initial condition µ 0 = δ X 0 , where ˆ α is the optimal feedback control. ⇒ A coupled system of a Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman PDE (backward) and a Fokker-Planck PDE (forward) Peter Tankov (ENSAE) A mean-field game of resource sharing June 25–29, 2018 10 / 31

  17. MFG of optimal stopping Outline 1 Introduction 2 Mean-field games 3 MFG of optimal stopping 4 MFG of optimal stopping: the relaxed control approach 5 Back to the game of resource sharing Peter Tankov (ENSAE) A mean-field game of resource sharing June 25–29, 2018 11 / 31

Download Presentation
Download Policy: The content available on the website is offered to you 'AS IS' for your personal information and use only. It cannot be commercialized, licensed, or distributed on other websites without prior consent from the author. To download a presentation, simply click this link. If you encounter any difficulties during the download process, it's possible that the publisher has removed the file from their server.

Recommend


More recommend