advertising and voter data in asymmetric political
play

Advertising and Voter Data in Asymmetric Political Contests - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

Advertising and Voter Data in Asymmetric Political Contests Priyanka Sharma Liad Wagman 31 January 2020 Priyanka Sharma and Liad Wagman Advertising and Voter Data in Asymmetric Political Contests 0 / 17 Motivation According to a recent FTC


  1. Advertising and Voter Data in Asymmetric Political Contests Priyanka Sharma Liad Wagman 31 January 2020 Priyanka Sharma and Liad Wagman Advertising and Voter Data in Asymmetric Political Contests 0 / 17

  2. Motivation According to a recent FTC Report on data brokers, “...one data broker’s database has information on 1.4 billion consumer transactions and over 700 billion aggregated data elements; another data broker’s database covers 1 trillion dollars in consumer transactions; and yet another data broker adds 3 billion new records each month to its databases.” Concomitant rise in political campaign spending, especially advertising on social media platforms. In 2016 elections, $1.4 billion were spent on digital advertising exhibiting a growth rate of 789% from 2012. Social media platforms assist data intermediaries in collecting information on voters’ preferences. Increased interest in understanding the links between data intermediaries, social media platforms and election outcomes. Priyanka Sharma and Liad Wagman Advertising and Voter Data in Asymmetric Political Contests 1 / 17

  3. Key findings How candidates’ access to voter pertinent data alter candidates’ campaign advertising expenditure? Candidates’ campaign advertising expenditure is dependent on voters’ predisposition and degree of data access. This has implications for profits of social media platform that is the recipient of advertising revenues. profits of data intermediary that receives revenue from sale of voter data to candidates. expected outcomes of election contest. While FCC regulates advertising sales prices to political campaigns, there is no law governing candidates’ access to voter pertinent information. Priyanka Sharma and Liad Wagman Advertising and Voter Data in Asymmetric Political Contests 2 / 17

  4. Key findings Compare and contrast the incentives of intermediary and platform. The intermediary and the platform are always at conflict with respect to candidates’ information access. Social-media platform that is also used for advertising may have incentives to hinder an intermediary’s access to data. Either the intermediary or the platform always have an incentive to provide asymmetric data access to candidates. Alters the winning likelihood and potentially outcome of the election. Priyanka Sharma and Liad Wagman Advertising and Voter Data in Asymmetric Political Contests 3 / 17

  5. Model description Two candidates: Alice ( A ) and Bob ( B ). Candidates spend resources to convince voters to cast a vote in their favor. c A : Alice’s campaign spending. c B : Bob’s campaign spending. Voters have a “favorite”. Alice is the favorite, while Bob is the underdog (without loss of generality). x ∼ F (0 , 1): voters’ predisposition towards one of the candidates. Winning likelihood depends on relative campaign spending and x . c A Probability that Alice wins = c A + xc B Campaign spending takes the form of advertising on a media platform. Platform’s interest lies in maximizing candidates’ ad spending. Priyanka Sharma and Liad Wagman Advertising and Voter Data in Asymmetric Political Contests 4 / 17

  6. Model description A priori x is unknown to candidates, but they share a common prior over x . Candidates may learn x by procuring data from a data intermediary. Intermediary’s interest lies in maximizing revenue from sale of data. Depending upon whether candidates have access to data, four separate information regimes are possible. Non-exclusive access: (ND,ND): Neither candidates have data access. (Benchmark Case) 1 (D,D): Both candidates have data access. 2 Exclusive access: (D,ND): Only Alice has data access. 1 (ND,D): Only Bob has data access. 2 Candidates’ spending varies as a function of the prevailing information regime and x (if known). Priyanka Sharma and Liad Wagman Advertising and Voter Data in Asymmetric Political Contests 5 / 17

  7. Campaign spending under non-exclusive access 0.25 0.2 0.15 0.1 D,D c A 0.05 ND,ND c A 0 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 x Figure: Candidate A’s expenditure when x ∼ U (0 , 1) Priyanka Sharma and Liad Wagman Advertising and Voter Data in Asymmetric Political Contests 6 / 17

  8. Comparing non-exclusive access regimes The expected advertising expenditures for each candidate is identical under both non-exclusive (equal) access regimes. This implies that, ex-ante Expected outcome remains unchanged across the two regimes. Platform is indifferent between equal data access and no data access (provided candidates’ budgets are not binding, which we assume). Intermediary prefers equal data access (to profit from data sale). Candidates prefer no data access (lower overall spending). Priyanka Sharma and Liad Wagman Advertising and Voter Data in Asymmetric Political Contests 7 / 17

  9. Campaign spending when Alice obtains exclusive access There exists a cutoff x D , ND such that candidate A spends less when exclusively informed for x > x D , ND and spends more for x < x D , ND . 0.25 D,D c A 0.2 D,ND c A 0.15 0.1 0.05 0 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 x Figure: Candidate A’s ex-post spending when x ∼ U (0 , 1) Candidate B ’s spending equals expected spending by candidate A . Priyanka Sharma and Liad Wagman Advertising and Voter Data in Asymmetric Political Contests 8 / 17

  10. Campaign spending when Bob obtains exclusive access There exists an interval ( x ND , D , x ND , D ) such that candidate B spends more for x inside this interval and less for x outside this interval. 0.25 D,D c B 0.2 ND,D c B 0.15 0.1 0.05 0 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 x Figure: Candidate B’s expenditure when x ∼ U (0 , 1) Candidate A ’s spending equals expected spending by candidate B . Priyanka Sharma and Liad Wagman Advertising and Voter Data in Asymmetric Political Contests 9 / 17

  11. Platform’s preferences The platform’s preference over the information regimes depends on the distribution of x . 0.22 0.215 0.21 0.205 0.2 0.195 0.19 (D,D) (D,D) (D,ND) (D,ND) (ND,D) (ND,D) (D,D) (D,ND) (ND,D) Figure: Platform’s profits when x ∼ Beta (1 , 5) with support (0 , 1) Figure: Platform’s profits when x ∼ Beta (1 , 3) with support (0 , 1) Figure: Platform’s profits when x ∼ U (0 , 1) Priyanka Sharma and Liad Wagman Advertising and Voter Data in Asymmetric Political Contests 10 / 17

  12. Intermediary’s preferences The intermediary’s preference over the information regimes also depends on the distribution of x . (D,D) (D,ND) (ND,D) Figure: Intermediary’s profits when x ∼ U (0 , 1) Priyanka Sharma and Liad Wagman Advertising and Voter Data in Asymmetric Political Contests 11 / 17

  13. Conflict between Platform and Intermediary The sum of the platform’s and intermediary’s profits is constant across all data-access regimes. Their profit rankings of these regimes are mirror opposites. (D,D) (D,ND) (ND,D) (D,D) (D,ND) (ND,D) Figure: Platform’s profits when Figure: Intermediary’s profits when x ∼ U (0 , 1) x ∼ U (0 , 1) The intermediary’s and the platform’s profit motives are always in conflict! Priyanka Sharma and Liad Wagman Advertising and Voter Data in Asymmetric Political Contests 12 / 17

  14. Election outcome under non-exclusive access Candidates’ winning likelihoods remain unchanged under non-exclusive data access. 1 D,D A 0.9 ND,ND A 0.8 0.7 0.6 0.5 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 x Figure: Candidate A’s winning likelihood when x ∼ U (0 , 1) Priyanka Sharma and Liad Wagman Advertising and Voter Data in Asymmetric Political Contests 13 / 17

  15. Election outcome when Alice obtains exclusive access There exists a threshold x A such that A is less likely to win with exclusive access for x < x A and more likely to win for x > x A . 1 D,D A 0.9 D,ND A 0.8 0.7 0.6 0.5 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 x Figure: Candidate A’s winning likelihood when x ∼ U (0 , 1) Priyanka Sharma and Liad Wagman Advertising and Voter Data in Asymmetric Political Contests 14 / 17

  16. Election outcome when Bob obtains exclusive access There exists a threshold x B such that A is more likely to win when B has exclusive access for x < x B and less likely to win for x > x B . 1 D,D A 0.9 ND,D A 0.8 0.7 0.6 0.5 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 x Figure: Candidate A’s winning likelihood when x ∼ U (0 , 1) Priyanka Sharma and Liad Wagman Advertising and Voter Data in Asymmetric Political Contests 15 / 17

  17. Winning likelihoods Ex ante, candidates’ winning likelihoods in each data-access regime depend on the distribution of x . (D,D) (D,ND) (ND,D) Figure: Candidate A’s ex-ante winning likelihoods when x ∼ U (0 , 1) Priyanka Sharma and Liad Wagman Advertising and Voter Data in Asymmetric Political Contests 16 / 17

  18. Practical implications 1 Existence of a data intermediary alters candidates’ winning likelihoods and potentially influences the outcome of an election. 2 Either the intermediary or the platform always has an incentive for voter information to be exclusively shared with one of the candidates. 3 A social-media giant that is also a political advertising platform may have incentives to hinder an intermediary’s access to its data. Thank you for your attention! Priyanka Sharma and Liad Wagman Advertising and Voter Data in Asymmetric Political Contests 17 / 17

Download Presentation
Download Policy: The content available on the website is offered to you 'AS IS' for your personal information and use only. It cannot be commercialized, licensed, or distributed on other websites without prior consent from the author. To download a presentation, simply click this link. If you encounter any difficulties during the download process, it's possible that the publisher has removed the file from their server.

Recommend


More recommend