what is the expected return on the market
play

What is the Expected Return on the Market? Ian Martin London School - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

What is the Expected Return on the Market? Ian Martin London School of Economics Ian Martin (LSE) What is the Expected Return on the Market? 1 / 52 Returns on the stock market are predictable return t + 1 = price t + 1 + dividend t + 1 = price


  1. What is the Expected Return on the Market? Ian Martin London School of Economics Ian Martin (LSE) What is the Expected Return on the Market? 1 / 52

  2. Returns on the stock market are predictable return t + 1 = price t + 1 + dividend t + 1 = price t + 1 + dividend t + 1 price t price t price t | {z } | {z } capital gain dividend yield Naive investor : If I buy when the dividend yield is high, I will have a high return on average ‘Sophisticated’ investor : No! The high dividend yield—that is, low price—is a sign that the market anticipates that future dividends will be disappointing. I therefore expect that a low capital gain will offset the high dividend yield Empirically, it appears that the naive investor is right Ian Martin (LSE) What is the Expected Return on the Market? 2 / 52

  3. Ian Martin (LSE) What is the Expected Return on the Market? 3 / 52

  4. The equity premium Figure from John Campbell’s Princeton Lecture in Finance Ian Martin (LSE) What is the Expected Return on the Market? 4 / 52

  5. Motivation Find an asset price that forecasts expected returns I without using accounting data I without having to estimate any parameters I imposing minimal theoretical structure I and in real time Ian Martin (LSE) What is the Expected Return on the Market? 5 / 52

  6. A lower bound on the equity premium 1 year horizon, in % 20 15 10 5 0 2000 2005 2010 Ian Martin (LSE) What is the Expected Return on the Market? 6 / 52

  7. A lower bound on the equity premium 1 month horizon, annualized, in % 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 2000 2005 2010 Ian Martin (LSE) What is the Expected Return on the Market? 6 / 52

  8. Outline A volatility index, SVIX, gives a lower bound on the equity premium 1 SVIX and VIX 2 SVIX as a predictor variable 3 What is the probability of a 20% decline in the market? 4 Ian Martin (LSE) What is the Expected Return on the Market? 7 / 52

  9. Outline A volatility index, SVIX, gives a lower bound on the equity premium 1 SVIX and VIX 2 SVIX as a predictor variable 3 What is the probability of a 20% decline in the market? 4 Ian Martin (LSE) What is the Expected Return on the Market? 8 / 52

  10. Notation S T : level of S&P 500 index at time T R T : gross return on the S&P 500 from time t to time T R f , t : riskless rate from time t to time T M T : SDF that prices time- T payoffs from the perspective of time t We can price any time- T payoff X T either via the SDF or by computing expectations with risk-neutral probabilities: 1 E ⇤ time- t price of a claim to X T = E t ( M T X T ) = t X T R f , t Asterisks indicate risk-neutral quantities Ian Martin (LSE) What is the Expected Return on the Market? 9 / 52

  11. Risk-neutral variance and the risk premium As an example, we can write conditional risk-neutral variance as � � t R T ) 2 = R f , t E t t R 2 M T R 2 � R 2 var ⇤ t R T = E ⇤ T � ( E ⇤ (1) T f , t We can decompose the equity premium into two components: ⇥ ⇤ ⇥ ⇤ E t ( M T R 2 E t ( M T R 2 E t R T � R f , t = T ) � R f , t � T ) � E t R T 1 var ⇤ = t R T � cov t ( M T R T , R T ) R f , t The first line adds and subtracts E t ( M T R 2 T ) The second exploits equation (1) and the fact that E t M T R T = 1 Ian Martin (LSE) What is the Expected Return on the Market? 10 / 52

  12. Risk-neutral variance and the risk premium 1 var ⇤ E t R T � R f , t = t R T � cov t ( M T R T , R T ) R f , t | {z }  0, under the NCC The decomposition splits the risk premium into two pieces Risk-neutral variance can be computed from time- t asset prices The covariance term can be controlled: it is negative in theoretical models and in the data Formalize this key assumption as the negative correlation condition : cov t ( M T R T , R T )  0 Ian Martin (LSE) What is the Expected Return on the Market? 11 / 52

  13. The NCC holds. . . . . . in lognormal models in which the market’s conditional Sharpe 1 ratio exceeds its conditional volatility (Campbell–Cochrane 1999, Bansal–Yaron 2004, and many others). Ian Martin (LSE) What is the Expected Return on the Market? 12 / 52

  14. The NCC holds. . . . . . in lognormal models in which the market’s conditional Sharpe 1 ratio exceeds its conditional volatility (Campbell–Cochrane 1999, Bansal–Yaron 2004, and many others). . . . in a wide range of models with intertemporal investors, state 2 variables, Epstein–Zin preferences, non-Normality, labor income. Ian Martin (LSE) What is the Expected Return on the Market? 12 / 52

  15. The NCC holds. . . . . . in lognormal models in which the market’s conditional Sharpe 1 ratio exceeds its conditional volatility (Campbell–Cochrane 1999, Bansal–Yaron 2004, and many others). . . . in a wide range of models with intertemporal investors, state 2 variables, Epstein–Zin preferences, non-Normality, labor income. . . . if there is a one-period investor who maximizes expected utility, 3 who is fully invested in the market, and whose relative risk aversion γ ( C ) ⌘ � Cu 00 ( C ) u 0 ( C ) � 1 (not necessarily constant). Ian Martin (LSE) What is the Expected Return on the Market? 12 / 52

  16. The NCC holds. . . . . . in lognormal models in which the market’s conditional Sharpe 1 ratio exceeds its conditional volatility (Campbell–Cochrane 1999, Bansal–Yaron 2004, and many others). . . . in a wide range of models with intertemporal investors, state 2 variables, Epstein–Zin preferences, non-Normality, labor income. . . . if there is a one-period investor who maximizes expected utility, 3 who is fully invested in the market, and whose relative risk aversion γ ( C ) ⌘ � Cu 00 ( C ) u 0 ( C ) � 1 (not necessarily constant). I Proof. The given assumption implies that the SDF is proportional to u 0 ( W t R T ) , so we must show that cov t ( R T u 0 ( W t R T ) , R T )  0. Ian Martin (LSE) What is the Expected Return on the Market? 12 / 52

  17. The NCC holds. . . . . . in lognormal models in which the market’s conditional Sharpe 1 ratio exceeds its conditional volatility (Campbell–Cochrane 1999, Bansal–Yaron 2004, and many others). . . . in a wide range of models with intertemporal investors, state 2 variables, Epstein–Zin preferences, non-Normality, labor income. . . . if there is a one-period investor who maximizes expected utility, 3 who is fully invested in the market, and whose relative risk aversion γ ( C ) ⌘ � Cu 00 ( C ) u 0 ( C ) � 1 (not necessarily constant). I Proof. The given assumption implies that the SDF is proportional to u 0 ( W t R T ) , so we must show that cov t ( R T u 0 ( W t R T ) , R T )  0. I This holds because R T u 0 ( W t R T ) is decreasing in R T : its derivative is u 0 ( W t R T ) + W t R T u 00 ( W t R T ) = � u 0 ( W t R T ) [ γ ( W t R T ) � 1 ]  0. Ian Martin (LSE) What is the Expected Return on the Market? 12 / 52

  18. Whose equity premium? 1 var ⇤ E t R T � R f , t � t R T R f , t Does not require that everyone holds the market Does not assume that all economic wealth is invested in the market Simply ask: What is the equity premium perceived by a rational one-period investor who holds the market and whose risk aversion is at least 1? This question is a sensible benchmark even in the presence of constrained and/or irrational investors Ian Martin (LSE) What is the Expected Return on the Market? 13 / 52

  19. Comparison to Merton (1980) Merton (1980) suggested estimating the equity premium from equity premium = risk aversion ⇥ return variance Holds if marginal investor has power utility and the market follows a geometric Brownian motion No distinction between risk-neutral and real-world variance in a diffusion-based model (Girsanov’s theorem) The appropriate generalization relates the equity premium to risk-neutral variance I Bonus: Risk-neutral variance is directly measurable from asset prices Ian Martin (LSE) What is the Expected Return on the Market? 14 / 52

  20. Comparison to Hansen–Jagannathan (1991) 1 var ⇤ t R T  E t R T � R f , t  R f , t · σ t ( M T ) · σ t ( R T ) R f , t Left-hand inequality is the new result I Good: relates unobservable equity premium to an observable quantity I Bad: requires the negative correlation condition Right-hand inequality is the Hansen–Jagannathan bound I Good: no assumptions I Bad: neither side is observable Ian Martin (LSE) What is the Expected Return on the Market? 15 / 52

  21. How to measure risk-neutral variance 1 1 1 t R T ) 2 R f , t var ⇤ R f , t E ⇤ t R 2 R f , t ( E ⇤ t R T = We want to measure T � Since E ⇤ R f , t E ⇤ 1 t S 2 t R T = R f , t , this boils down to calculating T That is: how can we price the ‘squared contract’ with payoff S 2 T ? Ian Martin (LSE) What is the Expected Return on the Market? 16 / 52

  22. How to measure risk-neutral variance How can we price the ‘squared contract’ with payoff S 2 T ? Suppose you buy: I 2 calls with strike K = 0 . 5 I 2 calls with strike K = 1 . 5 I 2 calls with strike K = 2 . 5 I 2 calls with strike K = 3 . 5 I etc . . . Ian Martin (LSE) What is the Expected Return on the Market? 17 / 52

  23. How to measure risk-neutral variance payoff 16 9 4 1 S T 0 1 2 3 4 T ⇡ 2 P R f , t E ⇤ 1 t S 2 So, K call t , T ( K ) R 1 1 R f , t E ⇤ t S 2 In fact, T = 2 0 call t , T ( K ) dK Ian Martin (LSE) What is the Expected Return on the Market? 18 / 52

Download Presentation
Download Policy: The content available on the website is offered to you 'AS IS' for your personal information and use only. It cannot be commercialized, licensed, or distributed on other websites without prior consent from the author. To download a presentation, simply click this link. If you encounter any difficulties during the download process, it's possible that the publisher has removed the file from their server.

Recommend


More recommend