v ertical structure and patent pools by sung hwan kim
play

V ertical Structure and Patent Pools by Sung-Hwan Kim. Review of - PDF document

V ertical Structure and Patent Pools by Sung-Hwan Kim. Review of Industrial Organization, 25:231-250, 2004. 1 Overlapping and fragmanted patent rights, patent thickets (Heller and Eisenberg, 1998) to commercialize new


  1. V ertical Structure and Patent Pools by Sung-Hwan Kim. Review of Industrial Organization, 25:231-250, 2004. 1

  2. • Overlapping and fragmanted patent rights, ’ ’ patent thickets’ ’(Heller and Eisenberg, 1998) ∗ to commercialize new technol- ogy, obtain licences from multi- ple patentees. Slows down com- mercialization of new tech. ∗ Transaction costs and complements problem where distinct firms sell complementary inputs (an exam- ple is due to Cournot (1838) for copper and zinc producers) to the downstream firm (Shapiro, 2001). ∗ The firms fail to internalize the effect of their royalty rates on other (input) firms’demands (set too high royalty rates) ∗ If they form a patent pool, roy- 2

  3. alty rates decline, overcome com- plements pr. ( ↑ efficiency). ∗ Patent pool: set joint royalty rates to max. profits, overall price ↓ of final product, efficiency gain. • Shapiro (2001) shows a patent pool enhances efficiency by eliminating complements problem. • The author builds on by allowing for vertical integration (in real life many examples like DVD patent pools, Sony, Phillips..etc) of upstream and down- stream firms, also assumes Cournot- Nash comp. for downstream indus- try. • Suppliers produce distinct products, producers only produce a single prod- 3

  4. uct and all upstream firms have a patent over its product. • 4 cases author considers, �Without a patent pool (integration vs no integration) ∗ Effect of integratedness on final product price is ambigous ( ↓ dou- ble marginalization (-), ↑ rivals’ costs (+)) �With a patent pool (integration vs no integration) ∗ V ertical integration reduces prod- uct price (further) and ↑ the ef- ficiency gain of patent pools on welfare. 4

  5. Model • Patents in the pool are perfect com- plements. • Patent pool use linear pricing. • No uncertainty. • Downstream market: homogeneous goods. • Downstream firm buys licences of patents. • n vertically integrated firms V=–v1,v2,...,vn� , m only upstream segment firms U=–u1,u2,.., um� , s only downstream segment firms D=–d1,d2,...,ds� . In total m+n+s. • P(Q)=a-bQ, mkt demand. • Upstream cost of licensing=0, down- stream: c vi = c + r vi (i=1,..,n) and 5

  6. c di = c + r di (i=1,..,m). Also c < a. • Firms engage in two-stage non-cooperative game played once. �1st stage, upstream firms indepen- dently and simultaneously decide on their unit royalty rates – l v 1 , l v 2 , ..., l vn , l u 1 , l u 2 , .., l um � �If they form a patent pool, royalty rate l p . �2nd stage, downstream firms ob- serve these rates (costs for them) and determine their quantities in- dependently and simultaneously. • Licensing w/o VI firms (Benchmark case) • No VI (vertically integrated) firms, n=0 and m, s > 1. 6

  7. • Backwards induction, Cournot-Nash Equilibrium for s downstream sup- pliers (assume all firms produce in eq-m), di = sa − P X s c di Q ∗ = q ∗ (1) ( s + 1) b • If stage 2 eq-m is an interior solu- tion then c di = c + r di = c + P j l uj Now turn to stage 1 • Case 1: Absence of a Patent Pool: Individual upstream firm’ s (ui ∈ U) problem, l ui .Q ∗ ( l ui ) (2) max l ui • Then l ∗ ui = ( a − c ) / ( m +1) and r ∗ di = ui . m.l ∗ 7

  8. • P ∗ = a − bQ ∗ = c + X 1 > c + r ∗ di . Final good price is greater than MC, too high. • ∂P ∗ /∂m > 0 (complements prob- lem), downstream firms compete for upstream’s surplus, as m ↑ efficiency ↓ . • Case 2: Presence of a Patent Pool • 2nd stage industry supply, P = sa − s ( c + l p ) Q ∗ (3) ( s + 1) b Stage 1, upstream firms problem, l p .Q ∗ ( l p ) (4) max l p • l ∗ p = ( a − c ) / 2 p = a − bQ ∗ = c + X 2 > c + l ∗ p . • P ∗ 8

  9. • It can be shown that P m l ∗ ui > l ∗ p = ⇒ P ∗ > P ∗ p for m > 1. As m ↑ re- duction in P (due to patent pool) ↑ (patent pool ↑ efficiency) • Licensing w/ VI firms • Case 1: Absence of a Patent Pool: �Asymmetric cost conditions for down- stream firms; � c vi = c + P j 6 = i l vj + P l uj , c di = c + P j 6 = i l vj + P l uj • Author shows 2nd stage Q ∗ (Cournot- Nash eq-m) is an interior eq-m � Q ∗ = n ( a − c ) − ( n − 1) P n l vj − n P m l uj ( n + 1) b (5) • Given Q ∗ at 1st stage upstream firms 9

  10. max their profits. • Due to asymmetry, n of upstream firms (VI) objective is, X π ∗ q ∗ (6) max vi ( l vi ) + l vi vj ( l vi ) l vi j 6 = i � ∂ P q ∗ vj X = ∂π ∗ ∂π vi j 6 = i vi q ∗ + vj + l vi = 0 ∂l vi ∂l vi ∂l vi j 6 = i (7) • ∂π ∗ ∂l vi > 0 , the firm ↑ l vi to get more vi upstream profit. Highering the roy- alty makes firm more competitive in manufacturers market (keep rivals away from your innovation), this is raising rivals’costs. 10

  11. ∂ P q ∗ vj ∂l vi < 0 , marginal upstream loss. j 6 = i • • At optimum marginal gain = mar- ginal loss. • Specialized upstream firm (m firms), l ui .Q ∗ (8) max l ui • FOC = Q ∗ + l ui .∂Q ∗ ∂π ui (9) = 0 ∂l ui ∂l ui • Solve for l ∗ ui and l ∗ vi from (7) and (9) = ⇒ get Q ∗ and P ∗ = c + X 3 • Straightforward to show P ∗ > c + vi and P ∗ < c + r ∗ r ∗ di • All specialized downstream produc- ers (m firms) will be out (p < mc). 11

  12. Theorem 1 Consider an industry with at least one vertically integrated firm and no patent pool. Then in a sub- game perfect equilibrium, all the spe- cialized manufacturers are excluded and only the vertically integrated firms are active downstream. • Case 2: Presence of a Patent Pool • Upstream patent pool members max. joint profit and split it according to predetermined allocation rule ( θ v 1 , ..., θ vn , θ u 1 , ..., θ um ) • θ ui > 0 , θ vi ≤ 1 , P θ vi + P θ ui = 1 . • Now at 2nd stage, a VI firm’s quan- tity decision will affect pool’s profit, in turn, will affect their respective upstream profits according to the al- 12

  13. location rule. • Downstream firm’ s choices are vi and di subject to objective functions: π vi = ( a − bQ − c − l p ) q vi + θ vi l p Q (10) (11) π di = ( a − bQ − c − l p ) q di • At 1st stage upstream firm will choose to max. joint profit wr to l p , X X π ∗ π ∗ π pool = vi ( l p ) + ui ( l p ) n m (12) • Solving the above FOC for l ∗ p and p = c + X 4 . P ∗ > getting Q ∗ ⇒ P ∗ p = vi and P ∗ > c + r ∗ c + r ∗ di . 13

  14. Theorem 2 Consider an industry with at least one vertically integrated firm and a patent pool. Then, in the unique subgame perfect equilibrium, there is no exclusion of downstream firms ex- cept when P θ vi = 1 . • P θ vi = 1 is when all pool profit is shared among VI firms. As a summary, • No VI, prices are given by; P (0 , m, s ) = c +( ms + m + 1)( a − c ) ( m + 1)( s + 1) (13) P p (0 , m, s ) = c + ( s + 2)( a − c ) 2( s + 1) (14) 14

  15. • It can be shown that P p (0 , m, s ) < P (0 , m, s ) this holds always. • Under VI, prices are given by, P ( n, m, s ) = c + h ( m, n )( a − c ) for n > 1 v ( m, n ) (15) P p ( n, m, s ) = c + f ( θ vi , n, s ) ( a − c ) g ( θ vi , n, s ) 2 (16) • Not always P p ( n, m, s ) < P ( n, m, s ) . • Due to two offsetting effects �Raising rivals’ costs (makes roy- alty costs ↑ because VI firm wants to ↑ cost of rival downstream prod, so P ↑ ) �Reduced double marginalization (makes 15

  16. royalty costs ↓ because a VI firm uses its own patent, P ↓ ) • First effect dominates when there are relatively few VI firms (low n). • Second effect dominates when there are sufficiently many VI firms (high n). As n ↑ P ( n, m, s ) ↓ . 16

Download Presentation
Download Policy: The content available on the website is offered to you 'AS IS' for your personal information and use only. It cannot be commercialized, licensed, or distributed on other websites without prior consent from the author. To download a presentation, simply click this link. If you encounter any difficulties during the download process, it's possible that the publisher has removed the file from their server.

Recommend


More recommend