persistence predictability and portfolio planning
play

Persistence, Predictability and Portfolio Planning M.J. Brennan - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

Persistence, Predictability and Portfolio Planning M.J. Brennan UCLA Yihong Xia University of Pennsylvania Stocks are sometimes cheap and sometimes dear. Important for long run investors? Price/10 year Average Earnings 1880-2003 50


  1. Persistence, Predictability and Portfolio Planning M.J. Brennan – UCLA Yihong Xia – University of Pennsylvania

  2. Stocks are sometimes cheap and sometimes dear. Important for long run investors? Price/10 year Average Earnings 1880-2003 50 45 2000 40 1929 35 Price-Earnings Ratio 30 1901 1966 25 20 15 10 5 0 1860 1880 1900 1920 1940 1960 1980 2000 2020 Year

  3. Background � Academic studies have found: • stock returns predictable by such variables as Dividend yield, B/M, interest rates etc • But virtually no out of sample return predictability � Does this mean that investors should ignore time variation in returns and behave as though expected returns constant? � NO!

  4. We show that: � Return predictability that is of first order importance to long run investors will be: • associated with large price variation. • hard to detect using standard regression framework even when a perfect signal is available • hard to estimate for portfolio planning purposes � A promising alternative to popular academic predictors is forward looking forecasts of long run returns from DDM • Convert long run forecasts to short run

  5. A Simple Model of Return Predictability dP = μ + σ dt dz P P P μ = κ μ − μ + σ ( ) d dt dz μ μ Mean reverting expected return �

  6. Parameters for simulations chosen so that: � Unconditional distribution of μ is fixed at μ = ν = N ( 9 %, 4 %) • � varies a lot: 1 sigma interval (5% to 14%) � Consistent with a 14% annual stock return volatility � Risk free rate is constant at 3%, implying 6% equity premium. � Nine scenarios from the combination of ( ) κ = ρ = = − − 0 . 02 , 0 . 10 , 0 . 5 , and corr dz P dz , 0 . 0 , 0 . 5 , 0 . 9 u

  7. Strategy Use this (simulation) model to show this amount of expected return variability • Implies big variability in prices • Little short run return predictability an dis hard to detect • Possibly strong long run return predictability Later we will show: • The data consistent with this amount of predictability • How to exploit it

  8. P/D Ratios implied by the scenarios dD = + σ � Dividend Process: gdt dz D D D � Expected Rate of Return: + ⎡ ⎤ E Ddt dV ⎥ = μ μ = κ μ − μ + σ dt ⎢ d ( ) dt dz ⎣ ⎦ V μ μ � Differential equation allows us to solve for price as a function of dividend growth rate: P (D, μ ) = Pv( μ )

  9. Dividend yields can vary a lot as μ changes even though dividend growth assumed constant (g = 1.85%) 10% 9% mubar-sig 8% mubar mubar+sig 7% 6% 5% c 4% 3% 2% 1% 0% 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9

  10. � Under our scenarios • Prices vary a lot • Expected returns vary a lot (5%-13%) � Are we likely to detect this predictability by regressing returns on � (or proxies for � )? + τ = + μ + ε R t t ( , ) a b + τ t t t ,

  11. Distribution of corrected t -ratios on the predictor using 70 years of simulated monthly returns 3 25% Median 2.5 75% 2 1.5 1 0.5 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 Scenario

  12. R 2 (%) in an Annual Return Predictive Regression (70-years simulated returns) 14 25% 12 Median 75% 10 8 6 4 2 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9

  13. R 2 as a function of horizon for different values of κ and ρ 0.8 k=0.02,rh0=-0.9 k=0.10,rh0=-0.9 0.7 k=0.50,rh0=-0.9 k=0.02,rh0=-0.5 k=0.10,rh0=-0.5 k=0.50,rh0=-0.5 0.6 k=0.02,rh0=0.0 k=0.10,rh0=0.0 k=0.50,rh0=0.0 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 0.0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 Years

  14. � Short run predictability is hard to detect and measure. � Would it be valuable if we could detect it? e.g observe �

  15. Economic Value of Market Timing � Investor is assumed to maximize expected CRRA utility ( RRA = 5) over terminal wealth. � Measure economic value using certainty equivalent wealth ratio between different strategies (CEWR) • Optimal dynamic strategy • Myopic strategy • Unconditional strategy

  16. Value of (optimal) dynamic strategy relative to unconditional strategy: CEW(O)/CEW(U) (T=20, σ P =0.14, σ μ =0.04, μ = 9%=mubar) Scenario (vi) ρ =-0.9, κ =0.1 1.6 1.5 1.4 R W 1.3 E C 1.2 1.1 1 0.5 -0.9 kappa 0.1 -0.5 rho 0 0.02

  17. Value of (optimal) dynamic strategy relative to myopic strategy: CEW(O)/CEW(M) (T=20, σ P =0.14, σ μ =0.04, μ = 9%=mubar) Scenario (vi) ρ =-0.9, κ =0.1 1.60 1.50 1.40 Ratio 1.30 CEW 1.20 1.10 1.00 -0.9 0.5 -0.5 rho 0.1 kappa 0 0.02

  18. Value of Market Timing (CEWR ou ) for Investors with 20-year horizon 1 year R 2 tells us nothing about value of timing 1.6 κ =0.1 ρ =-0.9 κ =0.5 1.5 ρ =-0.9 R 2 =4.8% 1.4 u o R W E κ =0.5 C κ =0.02 1.3 ρ =-0.5 ρ =-0.9 R 2 =7.4% 1.2 κ =0.5 1.1 ρ =0.0 1.0 0.04 0.045 0.05 0.055 0.06 0.065 0.07 0.075 0.08 One-Year R 2

  19. � Market timing valuable if we could observe � . � But in practice we can only rely on proxies for � (dividend yields) and badly estimated regression coefficients. � A better approach is to rely on direct estimates of � that do not rely on regression estimates

  20. A Forward-Looking Method: DDM Model [ ] E D ∞ � DCF approach = ∑ + τ t t P ( ) τ + t 1 k τ = 1 t • Forecasts of future dividends provided by analysts yield current estimates of long run expected returns on stocks, k t • Problem: How to map k into short run expected rate of return μ μ = κ μ − μ + σ d ( ) dt dz μ μ

  21. DDM approach to estimating � If we know the parameters of the Vasicek interest rate model � we can infer the short rate, r, from the long rate, l. In same way, if we know the parameters of � μ = κ μ − μ + σ μ d ( ) dt dz μ we can infer � from k t Iterative procedure for inferring � and updating parameters � Also estimate model in which dividend growth rate follows O- � U process:

  22. Four DDM k series • Arnott & Bernstein (A&B) (2002), and Ilmanen (IL) (2003) • 1950.1 - 2002.2 quarterly • real, ex-post (back-casted) • based on smoothed GDP growth rate • Barclays Global Investors (BGI) and Wilshire Associates (WA) • 1973.1 to 2002.2 monthly – converted to quarterly • nominal, ex-ante (real time) • using I/B/E/S consensus estimates

  23. Estimates of μ from the WA DDM k series (1973.Q1 to 2002.Q2) 30% 25% k4 μ4,1 20% μ4,2 15% 10% 5% 0% 1973 1976 1979 1982 1985 1988 1991 1994 1997 2000 200303 -5%

  24. Estimated μ process parameters � Similar across 4 models and Close to scenario (vi) Real Nominal Scenario (A&B) (IL) (BGI) (WA) (vi) 0.085 0.122 0.091 0.122 κ μ 0.1 (0.083) (0.115) (0.085) (0.095) 0.017 0.0196 0.024 0.034 σ μ 0.018 (0.017) (0.022) (0.021) (0.027) 0.042 0.040 0.056 0.068 ν μ 0.04 (0.042) (0.047) (0.052) (0.061) -0.98 -0.88 -0.81 -0.68 ρ μ P -0.9 (-0.98) (-0.89) (-0.66) (-0.71)

  25. Statistical Significance: In-Sample Quarterly Predictive Regressions � Regression: ⎡ − κ ⎤ − 0 . 25 1 . 0 e + = + μ + ε , 2 i ⎢ ⎥ R ( t , t 0 . 25 ) a a κ 0 1 t t ⎣ ⎦ = i 1 (A & B) , 2 (IL) , 3 (BGI) , 4 (WA) � Theoretical value: a 1 =1.0

  26. In-Sample Quarterly Predictive Regressions Results a_1 R 2 Predictor N (%) H0: a_1=1 0.874 209 μ 1,2 1.43 [1.60] (1950.Q2 – 2002. Q2) 0.701 209 μ 2,2 1.12 [1.27] (1950.Q2 - 2002. Q2) 1.026 117 μ 3,2 2.89 [1.69] (1973.Q2 to 2002.Q2) 0.924 117 μ 4,2 2.74 [1.66] (1973.Q2 to 2002.Q2)

  27. Economic Importance: Simulation of Market Timing and Unconditional Strategies � RRA = 5 μ − * = r � Unconditional Strategy: x γσ 2 P � Optimal Market Timing: μ − * = r x t plus hedging terms γσ 2 P � Risky asset: S&P500 � Riskless asset: 30 day T-Bill

  28. Proportion of Wealth Invested in Stocks 1.2 Unconditional (based on full sample mean) Unconditional (based on gradually updated sample mean) Optimal 1.0 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.2 0.0 Mar-73 Mar-75 Mar-77 Mar-79 Mar-81 Mar-83 Mar-85 Mar-87 Mar-89 Mar-91 Mar-93 Mar-95 Mar-97 Mar-99 Mar-01

  29. Wealth under optimal and unconditional Strategies for a 20-year horizon constrained investor using μ 4,2 (RRA = 5, 1973.Q2 -1993.Q1) 12 10 uncondtional optimal 8 6 4 2 0 Sep-73 Sep-75 Sep-77 Sep-79 Sep-81 Sep-83 Sep-85 Sep-87 Sep-89 Sep-91

  30. Wealth under optimal and unconditional Strategies for a 9-year horizon constrained investor using μ 4,2 (RRA = 5, 1993.Q2 - 2002.Q2) 2.5 Unconditional 2.0 Optimal 1.5 1.0 0.5 0.0 Jun-93 Jun-95 Jun-97 Jun-99 Jun-01

  31. Wealth under optimal and unconditional Strategies for a 29-year horizon constrained investor using μ 4,2 (RRA = 5, 1973.Q2 – 2002.Q2) 25 20 uncondtional optimal 15 10 5 0 Jun-73 Jun-76 Jun-79 Jun-82 Jun-85 Jun-88 Jun-91 Jun-94 Jun-97 Jun-00

  32. Conclusion � Time-varying expected returns economically important, even though • Hard to detect, measure � Substantial benefit from the optimal strategy � DDM discount rates are a useful input for long run investor. � Long run investors (pension, insurance) should hedge against changes in investment opportunities.

Download Presentation
Download Policy: The content available on the website is offered to you 'AS IS' for your personal information and use only. It cannot be commercialized, licensed, or distributed on other websites without prior consent from the author. To download a presentation, simply click this link. If you encounter any difficulties during the download process, it's possible that the publisher has removed the file from their server.

Recommend


More recommend