optimal portfolio under worst case scenarios
play

Optimal Portfolio Under Worst-Case Scenarios Carole Bernard (UW), - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

Optimal Portfolio Under Worst-Case Scenarios Carole Bernard (UW), Jit Seng Chen (UW) and Steven Vanduffel (Vrije Universiteit Brussel) Rennes, March 2012. Carole Bernard Optimal Portfolio 1/35 Introduction Diversification Strategies


  1. Optimal Portfolio Under Worst-Case Scenarios Carole Bernard (UW), Jit Seng Chen (UW) and Steven Vanduffel (Vrije Universiteit Brussel) Rennes, March 2012. Carole Bernard Optimal Portfolio 1/35

  2. Introduction Diversification Strategies Cost-Efficiency Tail Dependence Numerical Example Conclusions Proofs Contributions 1 A better understanding of the link between Growth Optimal Portfolio and optimal investment strategies 2 Understanding issues with traditional diversification strategies and how lowest outcomes of optimal strategies always happen in the worse states of the economy . 3 Develop innovative strategies to cope with this observation. 4 Implications in terms of assessing the risk and return of a strategy and in terms of reducing systemic risk Carole Bernard Optimal Portfolio 2/35

  3. Introduction Diversification Strategies Cost-Efficiency Tail Dependence Numerical Example Conclusions Proofs Part I: Traditional Diversification Strategies Carole Bernard Optimal Portfolio 3/35

  4. Introduction Diversification Strategies Cost-Efficiency Tail Dependence Numerical Example Conclusions Proofs Growth Optimal Portfolio (GOP) • The Growth Optimal Portfolio (GOP) maximizes expected logarithmic utility from terminal wealth. • It has the property that it almost surely accumulates more wealth than any other strictly positive portfolios after a sufficiently long time . • Under general assumptions on the market, the GOP is a diversified portfolio. • Details in Platen (2006). Carole Bernard Optimal Portfolio 4/35

  5. Introduction Diversification Strategies Cost-Efficiency Tail Dependence Numerical Example Conclusions Proofs Growth Optimal Portfolio (GOP) • The Growth Optimal Portfolio (GOP) maximizes expected logarithmic utility from terminal wealth. • It has the property that it almost surely accumulates more wealth than any other strictly positive portfolios after a sufficiently long time . • Under general assumptions on the market, the GOP is a diversified portfolio. • Details in Platen (2006). Carole Bernard Optimal Portfolio 4/35

  6. Introduction Diversification Strategies Cost-Efficiency Tail Dependence Numerical Example Conclusions Proofs For example, in the Black-Scholes model • A Black-Scholes financial market (mainly for ease of exposition) • Risk-free asset { B t = B 0 e rt , t � 0 } •  dS 1 t = µ 1 dt + σ 1 dW 1 t  t S 1 , (1) dS 2 t = µ 2 dt + σ 2 dW t t  S 2 where W 1 and W are two correlated Brownian motions under the physical probability measure P . W t = ρ W 1 � 1 − ρ 2 W 2 t + t where W 1 and W 2 are independent. Carole Bernard Optimal Portfolio 5/35

  7. Introduction Diversification Strategies Cost-Efficiency Tail Dependence Numerical Example Conclusions Proofs Constant-Mix Strategy • Dynamic rebalancing to preserve the initial target allocation • The payoff of a constant-mix strategy is S π t = S π 0 exp( X π t ) where X π t is normal. • For an initial investment V 0 , V T is given by S π T V T = V 0 , S π 0 where π is the vector of proportions. Carole Bernard Optimal Portfolio 6/35

  8. Introduction Diversification Strategies Cost-Efficiency Tail Dependence Numerical Example Conclusions Proofs Growth Optimal Portfolio (GOP) In the 2-dimensional Black-Scholes setting, • The GOP is a constant-mix strategy with µ π − 1 X π � 2 σ 2 � t + σ π W π t = t , that maximizes the expected π growth rate µ π − 1 2 σ 2 π . It is π ⋆ = Σ − 1 · ( µ − r 1 ) . (2) • constant-mix portfolios given by π = απ ⋆ with α > 0 and where π ⋆ is the optimal proportion for the GOP, are optimal strategies for CRRA expected utility maximizers. With a constant relative risk aversion coefficient η > 0, CRRA utility is � x 1 − η when η � = 1 1 − η U ( x ) = log( x ) when η = 1 , and α = 1 /η . Carole Bernard Optimal Portfolio 7/35

  9. Introduction Diversification Strategies Cost-Efficiency Tail Dependence Numerical Example Conclusions Proofs Market Crisis The growth optimal portfolio S ⋆ can also be interpreted as a major market index. Hence it is intuitive to define a stressed market (or crisis) at time T as an event where the market - materialized through S ⋆ - drops below its Value-at-Risk at some high confidence level. The corresponding states of the economy verify Crisis states = { S ⋆ T < q α } , (3) where q α is such that P ( S ⋆ T < q α ) = 1 − α and α is typically high (e.g. α = 0 . 98). Carole Bernard Optimal Portfolio 8/35

  10. Introduction Diversification Strategies Cost-Efficiency Tail Dependence Numerical Example Conclusions Proofs Srategy 1: GOP We invest fully in the GOP. In a crisis (GOP is low), our portfolio is low! Carole Bernard Optimal Portfolio 9/35

  11. Strategy 1 vs the Growth Optimal Portfolio 200 180 160 140 Strategy 1 120 100 80 60 60 80 100 120 140 160 180 200 Growth Optimal Portfolio, S ∗ ( T )

  12. Introduction Diversification Strategies Cost-Efficiency Tail Dependence Numerical Example Conclusions Proofs Srategy 2: Buy-and-Hold The buy-and-hold strategy is the simplest investment strategy. An initial amount V 0 is used to purchase w 0 units of the bank account and w i units of stock S i ( i = 1 , 2) such that V 0 = w 0 + w 1 S 1 0 + w 2 S 2 0 , and no further action is undertaken. Example with 1/3 invested in each asset (bank, S 1 and S 2 ) on next slide. Carole Bernard Optimal Portfolio 11/35

  13. Introduction Diversification Strategies Cost-Efficiency Tail Dependence Numerical Example Conclusions Proofs Srategy 2: Buy-and-Hold The buy-and-hold strategy is the simplest investment strategy. An initial amount V 0 is used to purchase w 0 units of the bank account and w i units of stock S i ( i = 1 , 2) such that V 0 = w 0 + w 1 S 1 0 + w 2 S 2 0 , and no further action is undertaken. Example with 1/3 invested in each asset (bank, S 1 and S 2 ) on next slide. Carole Bernard Optimal Portfolio 11/35

  14. Strategy 2 vs the Growth Optimal Portfolio 220 200 180 160 Strategy 2 140 120 100 80 60 60 80 100 120 140 160 180 200 Growth Optimal Portfolio, S ∗ ( T )

  15. Introduction Diversification Strategies Cost-Efficiency Tail Dependence Numerical Example Conclusions Proofs Strategy 3: Constant-Mix Strategy Example with 1/3 invested in each asset (bank, S 1 and S 2 ). Carole Bernard Optimal Portfolio 13/35

  16. Strategy 3 vs the Growth Optimal Portfolio 200 180 160 140 Strategy 3 120 100 80 60 60 80 100 120 140 160 180 200 Growth Optimal Portfolio, S ∗ ( T )

  17. Introduction Diversification Strategies Cost-Efficiency Tail Dependence Numerical Example Conclusions Proofs ◮ These three traditional diversification strategies do not offer protection during a crisis. ◮ In a more general setting, optimal strategies share the same problem... Carole Bernard Optimal Portfolio 15/35

  18. Introduction Diversification Strategies Cost-Efficiency Tail Dependence Numerical Example Conclusions Proofs Part II: Optimal portfolio selection for law-invariant preferences Carole Bernard Optimal Portfolio 16/35

  19. Introduction Diversification Strategies Cost-Efficiency Tail Dependence Numerical Example Conclusions Proofs Stochastic Discount Factor and Real-World Pricing : The GOP can be used as numeraire to price under P � Price of � � X T � = E Q [ e − rT X T ] = E P [ ξ T X T ] = E P S ⋆ X T at 0 T where S ⋆ 0 = 1. Carole Bernard Optimal Portfolio 17/35

  20. Introduction Diversification Strategies Cost-Efficiency Tail Dependence Numerical Example Conclusions Proofs Stochastic Discount Factor and Real-World Pricing : The GOP can be used as numeraire to price under P � Price of � � X T � = E Q [ e − rT X T ] = E P [ ξ T X T ] = E P S ⋆ X T at 0 T where S ⋆ 0 = 1. Carole Bernard Optimal Portfolio 17/35

  21. Introduction Diversification Strategies Cost-Efficiency Tail Dependence Numerical Example Conclusions Proofs Cost-efficient strategies (Dybvig (1988)) Optimal Portfolio Selection Problem: Consider an investor with fixed investment horizon : max U ( X T ) X T subject to a given “cost of X T ” (equal to initial wealth) • Law-invariant preferences X T ∼ Y T ⇒ U ( X T ) = U ( Y T ) • Increasing preferences X T ∼ F , Y T ∼ G , ∀ x , F ( x ) � G ( x ) ⇒ U ( X T ) � U ( Y T ) A strategy (or a payoff) is cost-efficient if any other strategy that generates the same distribution under P costs at least as much. The optimal strategy for U must be cost-efficient . Carole Bernard Optimal Portfolio 18/35

  22. Introduction Diversification Strategies Cost-Efficiency Tail Dependence Numerical Example Conclusions Proofs Cost-efficient strategies (Dybvig (1988)) Optimal Portfolio Selection Problem: Consider an investor with fixed investment horizon : max U ( X T ) X T subject to a given “cost of X T ” (equal to initial wealth) • Law-invariant preferences X T ∼ Y T ⇒ U ( X T ) = U ( Y T ) • Increasing preferences X T ∼ F , Y T ∼ G , ∀ x , F ( x ) � G ( x ) ⇒ U ( X T ) � U ( Y T ) A strategy (or a payoff) is cost-efficient if any other strategy that generates the same distribution under P costs at least as much. The optimal strategy for U must be cost-efficient . Carole Bernard Optimal Portfolio 18/35

Download Presentation
Download Policy: The content available on the website is offered to you 'AS IS' for your personal information and use only. It cannot be commercialized, licensed, or distributed on other websites without prior consent from the author. To download a presentation, simply click this link. If you encounter any difficulties during the download process, it's possible that the publisher has removed the file from their server.

Recommend


More recommend