non stationary time series cointegration and spurious
play

Non-Stationary Time Series, Cointegration and Spurious Regression - PDF document

Econometrics 2 Spring 2005 Non-Stationary Time Series, Cointegration and Spurious Regression Heino Bohn Nielsen 1 of 26 Outline (1) Combinations of non-stationary variables; cointegration de fi ned. (2) Economic equilibrium and error


  1. Econometrics 2 — Spring 2005 Non-Stationary Time Series, Cointegration and Spurious Regression Heino Bohn Nielsen 1 of 26 Outline (1) Combinations of non-stationary variables; cointegration de fi ned. (2) Economic equilibrium and error correction. (3) Cointegration regression. (4) Engle-Granger residual based test for no-cointegration. (5) Estimation and testing in the error correction model. (6) Empirical example: Danish interest rates. (7) Spurious regression: Example and simulation. 2 of 26

  2. Combinations of Non-Stationary Variables • Let W t = ( Y t X t ) 0 be two I(1) variables, i.e. they contain stochastic trends: X t Y t = Y 0 + i =1 � i + stationary process X t X t = X 0 + i =1 η i + stationary process. In general, a linear combination will also have a random walk component: ¢ µ ¶ ¡ 1 − β 1 Y t Z t = β 0 W t = = Y t − β 1 · X t X t X t X t = Y 0 − β 1 · X 0 + i =1 � i − β 1 · i =1 η i + stationary process. • Important exception: There exist a β = ( 1 − β 1 ) 0 , so that Z t is stationary. In this case we say that Y t and X t co-integrate with cointegration vector β . • Cointegration occurs if the stochastic trends in Y t and X t are the same: X t X t i =1 � i = β 1 · i =1 η i . 3 of 26 Cointegration and Economic Equilibrium • Consider a regression model for two I(1) variables, Y t and X t , given by Y t = β 0 + β 1 X t + � t . ( ∗ ) The term, � t , is interpretable as the deviation from the relation in ( ∗ ). • If Y t and X t cointegrate, then the deviation � t = Y t − β 0 − β 1 X t is a stationary process with attractor zero. Shocks to Y t and X t have permanent e ff ects; but Y t and X t co-vary so that � t returns to zero. We think of ( ∗ ) as de fi ning an equilibrium between Y t and X t . • If Y t and X t do not cointegrate, then the deviation � t is I(1). There is no natural interpretation of ( ∗ ) as an equilibrium relation. 4 of 26

  3. Empirical Example: Consumption and Income • Time series for log consumption, C t , and log income, Y t , are likely to be I(1). De fi ne a vector W t = ( C t Y t ) 0 . • Consumption and income are cointegrated with cointegration vector β = ( 1 − 1 ) 0 if the (log-) consumption-income ratio, µ ¶ C t Z t = β 0 W t = ( 1 − 1 ) = C t − Y t , Y t is a stationary process. The consumption-income ratio is an equilibrium relation. Income ratio, log ( C t ) − log ( Y t ) Consumption and income, logs 0.00 Income Consumption 6.25 -0.05 -0.10 6.00 -0.15 1970 1980 1990 2000 1970 1980 1990 2000 5 of 26 How is the Equilibrium Sustained? • There must be forces pulling Y t or X t towards the attractor. • Famous representation theorem: Y t and X t cointegrate if and only if there exist an error correction model for either Y t , X t or both. • As an example, let Z t = Y t − β 1 X t be a stationary relation between I(1) variables. Then there exists a stationary AR model for Z t . Assume for simplicity an AR(2): Z t = θ 1 Z t − 1 + θ 2 Z t − 2 + v t , θ (1) = 1 − θ 1 − θ 2 > 0 . This is equivalent to ( Y t − β 1 X t ) = θ 1 ( Y t − 1 − β 1 X t − 1 ) + θ 2 ( Y t − 2 − β 1 X t − 2 ) + v t Y t = β 1 X t + θ 1 Y t − 1 − θ 1 β 1 X t − 1 + θ 2 Y t − 2 − θ 2 β 1 X t − 2 + v t , or ∆ Y t = β 1 ∆ X t + θ 2 β 1 ∆ X t − 1 − θ 2 ∆ Y t − 1 − (1 − θ 1 − θ 2 ) { Y t − 1 − β 1 X t − 1 } + v t . In this case we have a common-factor restriction. That is not necessarily true. 6 of 26

  4. OLS Regression with Cointegrated Series • In the cointegration case there exists a β 1 so that the error term, � t , in Y t = α + β 1 X t + � t . ( ∗∗ ) is stationary. • OLS applied to ( ∗∗ ) gives consistent results, so that b β 1 → β 1 for T → ∞ . • Note that consistency is obtained even if potential dynamic terms are neglected. This is because the stochastic trends in Y t and X t dominate. We can even get consistent estimates in the reverse regression X t = δ + γ 1 Y t + η t . • Unfortunately, it turns out that b β 1 is not asymptotically normal in general. The normal inferential procedures do not apply to b β 1 ! We can use ( ∗∗ ) for estimation—not for testing. 7 of 26 Super-Consistency • For stationary series, the variance of b β 1 declines at a rate of T − 1 . • For cointegrated I(1) series, the variance of b β 1 declines at a faster rate of T − 2 . • Intuition: If b β 1 = β 1 then � t is stationary. If b β 1 6 = β 1 then the error is I(1) and will have a large variance. The ’information’ on the parameter grows very fast. Stationary, T=50 Stationary, T=100 Stationary, T=500 30 30 30 20 20 20 10 10 10 0 0 0 0.5 1.0 1.5 0.5 1.0 1.5 0.5 1.0 1.5 Non-Stationary, T=50 Non-Stationary, T=500 Non-Stationary, T=100 30 30 30 20 20 20 10 10 10 0 0 0 0.5 1.0 1.5 0.5 1.0 1.5 0.5 1.0 1.5 8 of 26

  5. Test for No-Cointegration, Known β 1 • Suppose that we know that Y t and X t are I(1). Assume that β 1 is known. • The series cointegrate, with cointegration vector β = ( 1 − β 1 ) , if Z t = Y t − β 1 X t is stationary. • This can be tested using an ADF unit root test, e.g. the test for H 0 : π = 0 in p − 1 X ∆ Z t = δ + ∆ Z t − i + πZ t − 1 + η t . i =1 The usual DF critical values apply to t π =0 . • Note, that the null, H 0 : π = 0 , is a unit root, i.e. no cointegration. 9 of 26 Test for No-Cointegration, Estimated β 1 • Engle-Granger (1987) two-step procedure. • If β 1 is unknown, it can be (super-consistently) estimated in Y t = β 0 + β 1 X t + � t . ( ∗ ∗ ∗ ) b β = ( 1 − b β 1 ) is a cointegration vector if b � t is a stationary process. • This can be tested using a DF unit root test, e.g. the test for H 0 : π = 0 in p − 1 X ∆ b ∆ b � t − i + π b � t = � t − 1 + η t . i =1 The critical value for t π =0 depends on the deterministic regressors in ( ∗ ∗ ∗ ). • The fact that b β 1 is estimated also change the critical values. OLS in ( ∗ ∗ ∗ ) minimizes the variance of b � t . Look ’as stationary as possible’. Critical value depends on the number of regressors. 10 of 26

  6. 0.6 Estimated parameters in cointegrating regression (with constant in the regression (***)) 7 6 5 4 3 2 1 0.5 DF(constant) 0.4 N(0,1) 0.3 0.2 0.1 -8 -7 -6 -5 -4 -3 -2 -1 0 1 2 3 4 5 11 of 26 • Critical values for the Dickey-Fuller test for no-cointegration are given by: Case 1: A constant term in ( ∗ ∗ ∗ ). Number of variables Signi fi cance level incl. Y t 1% 5% 10% 2 − 3 . 90 − 3 . 34 − 3 . 04 3 − 4 . 29 − 3 . 74 − 3 . 45 4 − 4 . 64 − 4 . 10 − 3 . 81 5 − 4 . 96 − 4 . 42 − 4 . 13 Case 2: A constant and a trend in ( ∗ ∗ ∗ ). Number of variables Signi fi cance level incl. Y t 1% 5% 10% 2 − 4 . 32 − 3 . 78 − 3 . 50 3 − 4 . 66 − 4 . 12 − 3 . 84 4 − 4 . 97 − 4 . 43 − 4 . 15 5 − 5 . 25 − 4 . 72 − 4 . 43 12 of 26

  7. Dynamic Modelling • Given the estimated cointegrating vector we can de fi ne the error correction term � t = Y t − b β 0 − b ecm t = b β 1 X t , which is, per de fi nition, a stationary stochastic variable. • Since b β 1 converges to β 1 very fast we can treat it as a fi xed number and formulate an error correction model conditional on ecm t , i.e. ∆ Y t = δ + φ 0 ∆ X t + φ 1 ∆ X t − 1 + θ ∆ Y t − 1 − γ · ecm t − 1 + v t . • Given cointegration, all terms are stationary, and normal inference applies to δ , φ 0 , φ 1 , θ , and γ . 13 of 26 Estimation of β In the ECM • The estimator of β 1 from a static regression is super-consistent, but often biased due to ignored dynamics. • An alternative estimator is based on an unrestricted error correction model, e.g. ∆ Y t = δ + θ ∆ Y t − 1 + φ 0 ∆ X t + φ 1 ∆ X t − 1 + γ 1 Y t − 1 + γ 2 X t − 1 + v t , ( # ) which is equivalent to the unrestricted ADL regression Y t = δ + α 1 Y t − 1 + α 2 Y t − 2 + κ 1 X t + κ 2 X t − 1 + κ 3 X t − 2 + v t . An estimate of β 1 can be found as the parameter in the long-run solutions: β 1 = − b γ 2 b = ( b κ 1 + b κ 2 + b κ 3 ) / (1 − b α 1 − b α 2 ) . b γ 1 • The main advantage is that the analysis is undertaken in a well-speci fi ed model. The approach is optimal if only Y t error corrects. 14 of 26

  8. Testing for No-Cointegration in the ECM • Due to representation theorem, the null hypothesis of no-cointegration corre- sponds to the null of no-error-correction. • Several tests have been designed in this spirit. • The most convenient is the so-called PcGive test for no-cointegration. It is based on the unrestricted ECM: ∆ Y t = δ + θ ∆ Y t − 1 + φ 0 ∆ X t + φ 1 ∆ X t − 1 + γ 1 Y t − 1 + γ 2 X t − 1 + � t , ( # ) and tests the hypothesis H 0 : γ 1 = 0 against the cointegration alternative, γ 1 < 0 . • The distribution of the t − ratio, b γ 1 t γ 1 =0 = γ 1 ) , SE ( b depends on the deterministic terms and the number of regressors in ( # ). 15 of 26 • Critical values for the PcGive test for no-cointegration are given by: Case 1: A constant term in ( # ). Number of variables Signi fi cance level incl. Y t 1% 5% 10% 2 − 3 . 79 − 3 . 21 − 2 . 91 3 − 4 . 09 − 3 . 51 − 3 . 19 4 − 4 . 36 − 3 . 76 − 3 . 44 5 − 4 . 59 − 3 . 99 − 3 . 66 Case 2: A constant and a trend in ( # ). Number of variables Signi fi cance level incl. Y t 1% 5% 10% 2 − 4 . 25 − 3 . 69 − 3 . 39 3 − 4 . 50 − 3 . 93 − 3 . 62 4 − 4 . 72 − 4 . 14 − 3 . 83 5 − 4 . 93 − 4 . 34 − 4 . 03 16 of 26

Download Presentation
Download Policy: The content available on the website is offered to you 'AS IS' for your personal information and use only. It cannot be commercialized, licensed, or distributed on other websites without prior consent from the author. To download a presentation, simply click this link. If you encounter any difficulties during the download process, it's possible that the publisher has removed the file from their server.

Recommend


More recommend