non stationary time series and unit root tests
play

Non-Stationary Time Series and Unit Root Tests Heino Bohn Nielsen - PDF document

Econometrics 2 Fall 2005 Non-Stationary Time Series and Unit Root Tests Heino Bohn Nielsen 1 of 25 Introduction Many economic time series are trending. Important to distinguish between two important cases: (1) A stationary process


  1. Econometrics 2 — Fall 2005 Non-Stationary Time Series and Unit Root Tests Heino Bohn Nielsen 1 of 25 Introduction • Many economic time series are trending. • Important to distinguish between two important cases: (1) A stationary process with a deterministic trend: Shocks have transitory e ff ects. (2) A process with a stochastic trend or a unit root: Shocks have permanent e ff ects. • Why are unit roots important? (1) Interesting to know if shocks have permanent or transitory e ff ects. (2) It is important for forecasting to know if the process has an attractor. (3) Stationarity was required to get a LLN and a CLT to hold. For unit root processes, many asymptotic distributions change! Later we look at regressions involving unit root processes: spurious regression and cointegration. 2 of 25

  2. Outline of the Lecture (1) Di ff erence between trend stationarity and unit root processes. (2) Unit root testing. (3) Dickey-Fuller test. (4) Caution on deterministic terms. (5) An alternative test (KPSS). 3 of 25 Trend Stationarity • Consider a stationary AR(1) model with a deterministic linear trend term: Y t = θY t − 1 + δ + γt + � t , t = 1 , 2 , ..., T, ( ∗ ) where | θ | < 1 , and Y 0 is an initial value. • The solution for Y t (MA-representation) has the form Y t = θ t Y 0 + µ + µ 1 t + � t + θ� t − 1 + θ 2 � t − 2 + θ 3 � t − 3 + ... Note that the mean, E [ Y t ] = θ t Y 0 + µ + µ 1 t → µ + µ 1 t for T → ∞ , contains a linear trend, while the variance is constant: σ 2 V [ Y t ] = V [ � t + θ� t − 1 + θ 2 � t − 2 + ... ] = σ 2 + θ 2 σ 2 + θ 4 σ 2 + ... = 1 − θ 2 . 4 of 25

  3. • The original process, Y t , is not stationary. The deviation from the mean, y t = Y t − E [ Y t ] = Y t − µ − µ 1 t is a stationary process. The process Y t is called trend-stationary. • The stochastic part of the process is stationary and shocks have transitory e ff ects We say that the process is mean reverting. Also, we say that the process has an attractor, namely the mean, µ + µ 1 t . • We can analyze deviations from the mean, y t . From the Frisch-Waugh theorem this is the same as a regression including a trend. 5 of 25 Shock to a Trend-Stationarity Process y t =0.8 ⋅ y t − 1 +ε t 15.0 Y t = y t + 0.1 ⋅ t 12.5 10.0 7.5 5.0 2.5 0.0 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100 6 of 25

  4. Unit Root Processes • Consider the AR(1) model with a unit root, θ = 1 : Y t = Y t − 1 + δ + � t , t = 1 , 2 , ..., T, ( ∗∗ ) or ∆ Y t = δ + � t , where Y 0 is the initial value. • Note that z = 1 is a root in the autoregressive polynomial, θ ( L ) = (1 − L ) . θ ( L ) is not invertible and Y t is non-stationary. • The process ∆ Y t is stationary. We denote Y t a di ff erence stationary process. • If ∆ Y t is stationary while Y t is not, Y t is called integrated of fi rst order, I(1). A process is integrated of order d , I( d ), if it contains d unit roots. 7 of 25 • The solution for Y t is given by X t X t X t Y t = Y 0 + ∆ Y i = Y 0 + ( δ + � i ) = Y 0 + δt + � i , i =1 i =1 i =1 with moments V [ Y t ] = t · σ 2 E [ Y t ] = Y 0 + δt and Remarks: (1) The e ff ect of the initial value, Y 0 , stays in the process. (2) The innovations, � t , are accumulated to a random walk, P � i . This is denoted a stochastic trend. Note that shocks have permanent e ff ects. (3) The constant δ is accumulated to a linear trend in Y t . The process in ( ∗∗ ) is denoted a random walk with drift. (4) The variance of Y t grows with t . (5) The process has no attractor. 8 of 25

  5. Shock to a Unit Root Process y t = y t − 1 +ε t 2 0 -2 -4 -6 -8 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100 9 of 25 Unit Root Tests • A good way to think about unit root tests: We compare two relevant models : H 0 and H A . (1) What are the properties of the two models? (2) Do they adequately describe the data? (3) Which one is the null hypothesis? • Consider two alternative test: (1) Dickey-Fuller test: H 0 is a unit root, H A is stationarity. (2) KPSS test: H 0 is stationarity, H A is a unit root. • Often di ffi cult to distinguish in practice (Unit root tests have low power). Many economic time series are persistent, but is the root 0 . 95 or 1 . 0 ? 10 of 25

  6. The Dickey-Fuller (DF) Test • Idea: Set up an autoregressive model for y t and test if θ (1) = 0 . • Consider the AR(1) regression model y t = θy t − 1 + � t . The unit root null hypothesis against the stationary alternative corresponds to H 0 : θ = 1 against H A : θ < 1 . • Alternatively, the model can be formulated as ∆ y t = ( θ − 1) y t − 1 + � t = πy t − 1 + � t , where π = θ − 1 = θ (1) . The unit root hypothesis translates into H 0 : π = 0 against H A : π < 0 . 11 of 25 • The Dickey-Fuller (DF) test is simply the t − test for H 0 : b b θ − 1 π τ = b = π ) . se ( b se ( b θ ) The asymptotic distribution of b τ is not normal! The distribution depends on the deterministic components. In the simple case, the 5% critical value (one-sided) is − 1 . 95 and not − 1 . 65 . Remarks: (1) The distribution only holds if the errors � t are IID (check that!) If autocorrelation, allow more lags. (2) In most cases, MA components are approximated by AR lags. The distribution for the test of θ (1) = 0 also holds in an ARMA model. 12 of 25

  7. Augmented Dickey-Fuller (ADF) test • The DF test is extended to an AR(p) model. Consider an AR(3): y t = θ 1 y t − 1 + θ 2 y t − 2 + θ 3 y t − 3 + � t . A unit root in θ ( L ) = 1 − θ 1 L − θ 2 L 2 − θ 3 L 3 corresponds to θ (1) = 0 . • The test is most easily performed by rewriting the model: y t − y t − 1 = ( θ 1 − 1) y t − 1 + θ 2 y t − 2 + θ 3 y t − 3 + � t y t − y t − 1 = ( θ 1 − 1) y t − 1 + ( θ 2 + θ 3 ) y t − 2 + θ 3 ( y t − 3 − y t − 2 ) + � t y t − y t − 1 = ( θ 1 + θ 2 + θ 3 − 1) y t − 1 + ( θ 2 + θ 3 )( y t − 2 − y t − 1 ) + θ 3 ( y t − 3 − y t − 2 ) + � t ∆ y t = πy t − 1 + c 1 ∆ y t − 1 + c 2 ∆ y t − 2 + � t , where π = θ 1 + θ 2 + θ 3 − 1 = − θ (1) c 1 = − ( θ 2 + θ 3 ) c 2 = − θ 3 . 13 of 25 • The hypothesis θ (1) = 0 again corresponds to H 0 : π = 0 against H A : π < 0 . The t − test for H 0 is denoted the augmented Dickey-Fuller (ADF) test. • To determine the number of lags, k , we can use the normal procedures. — General-to-speci fi c testing: Start with k max and delete insigni fi cant lags. — Estimate possible models and use information criteria. — Make sure there is no autocorrelation. • Verbeek suggests to calculate the DF test for all values of k . This is a robustness check, but be careful! Why would we look at tests based on inferior/misspeci fi ed models? • An alternative to the ADF test is to correct the DF test for autocorrelation. Phillips-Perron non-parametric correction based on HAC standard errors. Quite complicated and likely to be inferior in small samples. 14 of 25

  8. Deterministic Terms in the DF Test • The deterministic speci fi cation is important: — We want an adequate model for the data. — The deterministic speci fi cation changes the asymptotic distribution. • If the variable has a non-zero level, consider a regression model of the form ∆ Y t = πY t − 1 + c 1 ∆ y t − 1 + c 2 ∆ y t − 2 + δ + � t . The ADF test is the t − test, b τ c = b π/ se ( b π ) . The critical value at a 5% level is − 2 . 86 . • If the variable has a deterministic trend, consider a regression model of the form ∆ Y t = πY t − 1 + c 1 ∆ y t − 1 + c 2 ∆ y t − 2 + δ + γt + � t . The ADF test is the t − test, b τ t = b π/ se ( b π ) . The critical value at a 5% level is − 3 . 41 . 15 of 25 The DF Distributions DF with a linear trend, τ t 0.5 DF with a constant, τ c DF, τ 0.4 N(0,1) 0.3 0.2 0.1 -5 -4 -3 -2 -1 0 1 2 3 4 16 of 25

  9. Empirical Example: Danish Bond Rate 0.200 0.175 0.150 Bond rate, r t 0.125 0.100 0.075 0.050 First difference, ∆ r t 0.025 0.000 -0.025 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 17 of 25 • An AR(4) model gives ∆ r t = − 0 . 0093 ( − 0 . 672) r t − 1 + 0 . 4033 (4 . 49) ∆ r t − 1 − 0 . 0192 ( − 0 . 199) ∆ r t − 2 − 0 . 0741 ( − 0 . 817) ∆ r t − 3 + 0 . 0007 (0 . 406) . Removing insigni fi cant terms produce a model ∆ r t = − 0 . 0122 ( − 0 . 911) r t − 1 + 0 . 3916 (4 . 70) ∆ r t − 1 + 0 . 0011 (0 . 647) . The 5% critical value ( T = 100 ) is − 2 . 89 , so we do not reject the null of a unit root. • We can also test for a unit root in the fi rst di ff erence. Deleting insigni fi cant terms we fi nd a preferred model ∆ 2 r t = − 0 . 6193 ( − 7 . 49) ∆ r t − 1 − 0 . 00033 . ( − 0 . 534) Here we safely reject the null hypothesis of a unit root ( − 7 . 49 ¿ − 2 . 89) . • Based on the test we concluce that r t is non-stationary while ∆ r t is stationary. That is r t ∼ I (1) 18 of 25

Download Presentation
Download Policy: The content available on the website is offered to you 'AS IS' for your personal information and use only. It cannot be commercialized, licensed, or distributed on other websites without prior consent from the author. To download a presentation, simply click this link. If you encounter any difficulties during the download process, it's possible that the publisher has removed the file from their server.

Recommend


More recommend