games on networks yves zenou stockholm university and ifn
play

Games on Networks Yves Zenou (Stockholm University and IFN) Whos - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

Games on Networks Yves Zenou (Stockholm University and IFN) Whos Who in Networks. Wanted: the Key Player Coralio Ballester, Antoni Calv- Armengol and Yves Zenou Econometrica 2006 When ij > 0 , an increase in the e ff ort x j of


  1. Games on Networks Yves Zenou (Stockholm University and IFN)

  2. Who’s Who in Networks. Wanted: the Key Player Coralio Ballester, Antoni Calvó- Armengol and Yves Zenou Econometrica 2006

  3. When σ ij > 0 , an increase in the e ff ort x j of agent j creates an incentive for i to increase his level of activity x i . We then talk of strategic complementarity in e ff orts. When σ ij < 0 , instead, an extra e ff ort from j triggers a downards shift in i ’s e ff ort in response. We say that e ff orts are strategic substitutes .

  4. The General Model • We can decompose bilateral influences like ∑  −  I −  U   G    Local Net Self- Global Complementarity Substitutability Substitutability where G represents a network of local complementarities, 0 ≤ g ij ≤ 1

  5. I is the n − square identity matrix and U the n − square matrix of ones. Σ = − β I − γ U + λ G with β > 0 , γ ≥ 0 and λ > 0 . The pattern of bilateral in fl uences results from the com- bination of an idiosyncratic e ff ect, a global interaction e ff ect, and a local interdependence component. The idiosyncratic e ff ect re fl ects (part of) the concavity of the payo ff function in own e ff orts. The global interaction e ff ect is uniform across all players (matrix U ) and corresponds to a substitutability e ff ect across all pairs of players with value − γ ≤ 0 . The local interaction component captures the (relative) strategic complementarity in e ff orts that varies across pairs of players, with maximal strength λ and population pattern re fl ected by G .

  6. The decomposition is depicted in Figure 1. This is just a centralization ( β and λ are de fi ned with respect to γ ) followed by a normalization (the g ij s are in [0 , 1] ) of the cross e ff ects. The fi gure in the upper panel corresponds to σ ij of either sign (the case σ ij ≤ 0 , for all i 6 = j is similar) while the fi gure in the lower panel corresponds to σ ij ≥ 0 , for all i 6 = j (recall that we assume σ < 0 ).

  7. λ β γ σ σ σ ij σ 0 λ g ij γ = 0 β λ σ σ σ ij σ 0 λ g ij

  8. The General Model • Three players 2  1 u 1  x 1 , x 2 , x 3   x 1 − 3 x 1 2 x 1 x 2 − x 1 x 3 − 6 1/2 − 1 2  1 ∑  u 2  x 1 , x 2 , x 3   x 2 − 3 x 2 2 x 1 x 2  x 2 x 3 1/2 − 6 1 2 − x 1 x 2  x 1 x 3 − 1 − 6 1 u 3  x 1 , x 2 , x 3   x 3 − 3 x 3 1 0 0 1 1 1 0 3/4 0 ∑  − 5 − 1  2 0 1 0 1 1 1 3/4 0 1    −  −    0 0 1 1 1 1 0 1 0 2 1 3

  9. Explanation of this example: ⎛ ⎞ − 6 1 / 2 − 1 ⎜ ⎟ Σ = 1 / 2 − 6 1 ⎝ ⎠ − 1 1 − 6 σ = min { σ ij } = − 1 and σ = max { σ ij } = 1 OBS: σ and σ do not include σ ii = σ . σ ii = σ = − 6 γ = − min { σ, 0 } = − min { − 1 , 0 } = 1 λ = σ + γ = 1 + γ = 2

  10. g ij = σ ij + γ but 0 ≤ g ij ≤ 1 λ Thus ⎛ n − 6+1 o ⎞ 1 / 2+1 = 3 − 1+1 max , 0 = 0 = 0 2 2 4 2 ⎜ ⎟ n − 6+1 o ⎜ ⎟ 1 / 2+1 = 3 1+1 G = ⎜ ⎟ max , 0 = 0 = 1 ⎝ 2 4 2 2 ⎠ n − 6+1 o − 1+1 1+1 = 0 = 1 max , 0 = 0 2 2 2 As a result Σ = − β I − γ U + λ G = − 5 × I − 1 × U + 2 × G

  11. In our example, we have: α = 1 , γ = 1 , λ = 2 , β = 5 Since for all i = 1 , 2 , 3 3 3 X X u i = αx i − 1 2 ( β − γ ) x 2 i − γ x i x j + λ g ij x i x j j =1 j =1 we have: 3 3 X X = αx 1 − 1 2 ( β − γ ) x 2 u 1 1 − γ x 1 x j + λ g 1 j x 1 x j j =1 j =1 = x 1 − 1 1 − x 1 x 1 − x 1 x 2 − x 1 x 3 + 23 24 x 2 4 x 1 x 2 1 + 1 = x 1 − 3 x 2 2 x 1 x 2 − x 1 x 3 Similarly 2 + 1 u 2 = x 2 − 3 x 2 2 x 1 x 2 + x 2 x 3 u 3 = x 3 − 3 x 2 3 − x 1 x 2 + x 1 x 3

  12. The network Bonacich centrality To each network g , we associate its adjacency matrix G = [ g ij ]. Symmetric zero-diagonal square matrix that keeps track of the direct connections in g . The k th power G k = G ( k times ) G of the adjacency matrix G keeps ... track of indirect connections in g . The coe ffi cient g [ k ] ij in the ( i, j ) cell of G k gives the number of paths of length k in g between i and j .

  13. Example Network g with three individuals (star) t t t 2 1 3 Figure 1 Adjacency matrix : ⎡ ⎤ 0 1 1 ⎢ ⎥ G = 1 0 0 ⎣ ⎦ 1 0 0 ⎡ ⎤ ⎡ ⎤ 2 k 2 k 2 k 0 0 0 ⎢ ⎥ ⎢ ⎥ G 2 k = G 2 k +1 = 2 k − 1 2 k − 1 2 k and ⎦ , k ≥ 1 0 0 0 ⎣ ⎦ ⎣ 2 k − 1 2 k − 1 2 k 0 0 0

  14. ⎡ ⎤ 0 2 2 ⎢ ⎥ G 3 = 2 0 0 ⎣ ⎦ 2 0 0 G 3 : two paths of length three between 1 and 2: 12 → 21 → 12 and 12 → 23 → 32. no path of length three from i to i

  15. For all integer k , de fi ne: n X g [ k ] b k i ( g ) = ij j =1 This is the sum of all paths of length k in g starting from i . Next, let φ ≥ 0, and de fi ne: + ∞ X φ k b k b i ( g ,φ ) = i ( g ) k =0 This is the sum of all paths in g starting from i , where paths of length k are weighted by the geometrically decaying factor φ k .

  16. For φ small enough, this in fi nite sum takes on a fi nite value. + ∞ X φ k G k · 1 = [ I − φ G ] − 1 · 1 , b ( g , φ ) = (2) k =0 where 1 is the vector of ones. b ( g , φ ) Bonacich network centrality of parameter φ in g . b i ( g ,φ ) as the Bonacich centrality of agent i in g . To each agent, it associates a value that counts the total number of direct and indirect (weighted) paths in the network stemming from this agent.

  17. Example Consider the network g in Figure 1. t t t 2 1 3 Figure 1 When φ is small enough, the vector of Bonacich network centralities is: ⎡ ⎤ ⎡ ⎤ b 1 ( g , φ ) 1 + 2 φ 1 ⎢ ⎥ ⎢ ⎥ b ( g , φ ) = b 2 ( g , φ ) ⎦ = 1 + φ ⎦ . ⎣ ⎣ 1 − 2 φ 2 b 3 ( g, φ ) 1 + φ

  18. The Bonacich centrality of node i is b i ( g , a ) = P n j =1 m ij ( g , a ) , and counts the total number of paths in g starting from i . It is the sum of all loops starting from i and ending at i , and all outer paths that connect i to every other player j 6 = i : X b i ( g , a ) = m ii ( g , a ) + m ij ( g , a ) . | {z } | {z } j 6 = i self − loops out − paths Note that, by de fi nition, m ii ( g , a ) ≥ 1 , and thus b i ( g , a ) ≥ 1 .

  19. Example 2. Consider the network g in Figure 1. t t t 2 1 3 Figure 1 ³ 2 1 / 2 ´ Largest eigenvalue: 2 1 / 2 . When d < c , the unique Nash equilib- rium is: 1 = a c + 2 d 3 = a c + d x ∗ x ∗ 2 = x ∗ and c 2 − 2 d 2 . c 2 − 2 d 2

  20. Dyads No social interactions. Then, the utility of each agent i would be given by: u i ( x i ) = αx i − 1 2 x 2 i The unique symmetric equilibrium is: x ∗ ni = α

  21. Now, in order to understand the general model and to see the role of λ and γ , let us take the simplest possible network, that is n = 2 and each player has a link with the other, that is g 12 = g 21 = 1 . The adjacency matrix à ! 0 1 G = 1 0 Two eigenvalues: 1 , − 1 . Thus µ 1 ( G ) = 1 . The network locations in g are interchangeable. In this case, the utility is now given by: ³ ´ u i ( x 1 , x 2 ) = αx i − 1 2 x 2 x 2 i − γ i + x i x j + λx i x j where 0 ≤ γ < 1 . Compared to our utility function β = 1 + γ .

  22. The fi rst order condition are: ∂u i = α − (1 + 2 γ ) x i − ( γ − λ ) x j = 0 ∂x i Since we have a dyad, the unique symmetric equilibrium is given by: α x ∗ = 1 − λ + 3 γ Observe that since β = 1 + γ and µ 1 ( G ) = 1 , β > λµ 1 ( G ) ⇔ λ < 1 + γ Guarantees this solution to be strictly positive.

  23. Check with Theorem α x ∗ = β + γb ( g , λ/β ) b ( g , λ/β ) Here " # − 1 I − λ b ( g , a ) = β G · 1 "Ã ! Ã !# − 1 Ã ! − λ 1 0 0 1 1 = 0 1 1 0 1 β Ã ! − 1 Ã ! 1 − λ/β 1 = − λ/β 1 1 ⎛ ⎞ ⎛ ⎞ β 2 Ã ! λβ β 1 ⎜ β 2 − λ 2 β 2 − λ 2 ⎟ β − λ ⎝ ⎠ = = ⎝ ⎠ β 2 β 1 λβ β − λ β 2 − λ 2 β 2 − λ 2

  24. Thus ⎛ ⎞ à ! β x ∗ α β − λ ⎝ ⎠ 1 = x ∗ β β + γb ( g , λ/β ) 2 β − λ where 2 β b ( g , λ/β ) = b 1 ( g , λ/β ) + b 2 ( g , λ/β ) = β − λ We have à ! à ! α x ∗ β − λ +2 γ 1 = α x ∗ 2 β − λ +2 γ Now since β = 1 + γ , we have: à ! à ! α x ∗ 1 − λ +3 γ 1 = α x ∗ 2 1 − λ +3 γ

  25. Suppose fi rst that γ = 0 , i.e. there is no global substitu- ability. We obtain α x ∗ = 1 − λ In the dyad, agents rip complementarities from their part- ner, and choose an e ff ort level above the optimal value for an isolated agent ( x ∗ = α ). The factor 1 / (1 − λ ) > 1 is often referred to as the social multiplier . Suppose now that λ = 0 . We obtain α x ∗ = 1 + 3 γ Equilibrium e ff orts are decreasing in γ . Indeed, global substituabilities add to the idiosyncratic concavity in one’s e ff orts, an exhaust decreasing marginal returns below the optimal value for an isolated agent. The general expres- sion results from a combination of both e ff ects.

Download Presentation
Download Policy: The content available on the website is offered to you 'AS IS' for your personal information and use only. It cannot be commercialized, licensed, or distributed on other websites without prior consent from the author. To download a presentation, simply click this link. If you encounter any difficulties during the download process, it's possible that the publisher has removed the file from their server.

Recommend


More recommend