enterprise risk management through strategic allocation
play

Enterprise Risk Management Through Strategic Allocation of Capital - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

Introduction Static Risk Appetite Numerical Dynamic Conclusion Enterprise Risk Management Through Strategic Allocation of Capital Joint Work Jing Ai University of Hawaii Patrick Brockett Linda Golden University of Texas at Austin June


  1. Introduction Static Risk Appetite Numerical Dynamic Conclusion Objective Function max [E(returns from projects)+E(returns from assets)-insurance cost] K N � w ( P ) [1+ E ( r ( P ) � w ( A ) [1+ E ( r ( A ) max )]+ )] − ud (1+ θ ) µ i i j j w ( P ) , w ( A ) , u i =1 j =1 i j 11 / 33

  2. Introduction Static Risk Appetite Numerical Dynamic Conclusion Objective Function max [E(returns from projects)+E(returns from assets)-insurance cost] K N � w ( P ) [1+ E ( r ( P ) � w ( A ) [1+ E ( r ( A ) max )]+ )] − ud (1+ θ ) µ i i j j w ( P ) , w ( A ) , u i =1 j =1 i j w ( P ) : proportions of capital invested in projects i r ( P ) : random returns from projects i 11 / 33

  3. Introduction Static Risk Appetite Numerical Dynamic Conclusion Objective Function max [E(returns from projects)+E(returns from assets)-insurance cost] K N � w ( P ) [1+ E ( r ( P ) � w ( A ) [1+ E ( r ( A ) max )]+ )] − ud (1+ θ ) µ i i j j w ( P ) , w ( A ) , u i =1 j =1 i j w ( P ) : proportions of capital invested in projects i r ( P ) : random returns from projects i w ( A ) : proportions of capital invested in assets j r ( A ) : random returns from financial assets j 11 / 33

  4. Introduction Static Risk Appetite Numerical Dynamic Conclusion Objective Function max [E(returns from projects)+E(returns from assets)-insurance cost] K N � w ( P ) [1+ E ( r ( P ) � w ( A ) [1+ E ( r ( A ) max )]+ )] − ud (1+ θ ) µ i i j j w ( P ) , w ( A ) , u i =1 j =1 i j w ( P ) : proportions of capital invested in projects i r ( P ) : random returns from projects i w ( A ) : proportions of capital invested in assets j r ( A ) : random returns from financial assets j µ : expected unit direct hazard loss; θ : indirect hazard loss d : insurance loading; u : proportion of total hazard risk insured 11 / 33

  5. Introduction Static Risk Appetite Numerical Dynamic Conclusion Objective Function max [E(returns from projects)+E(returns from assets)-insurance cost] K N � w ( P ) [1+ E ( r ( P ) � w ( A ) [1+ E ( r ( A ) max )]+ )] − ud (1+ θ ) µ i i j j w ( P ) , w ( A ) , u i =1 j =1 i j w ( P ) : proportions of capital invested in projects i r ( P ) : random returns from projects i w ( A ) : proportions of capital invested in assets j r ( A ) : random returns from financial assets j µ : expected unit direct hazard loss; θ : indirect hazard loss d : insurance loading; u : proportion of total hazard risk insured 11 / 33

  6. Introduction Static Risk Appetite Numerical Dynamic Conclusion Chance Constraints Account for four major types of firm risks: project risk, financial risk, operational risk, hazard risk Serve as the tool to incorporate the firm’s risk appetite and risk prioritization decisions Overall liquidity/solvency likelihood constraint specifies the likelihood of being unable to meet obligations and intertwines all the decision variables together 12 / 33

  7. Introduction Static Risk Appetite Numerical Dynamic Conclusion Project Risk Constraint Project risk concerns the real business part of the firm 13 / 33

  8. Introduction Static Risk Appetite Numerical Dynamic Conclusion Project Risk Constraint Project risk concerns the real business part of the firm Project risk: P [projects returns ≤ threshold] ≤ (project risk appetite) 13 / 33

  9. Introduction Static Risk Appetite Numerical Dynamic Conclusion Project Risk Constraint Project risk concerns the real business part of the firm Project risk: P [projects returns ≤ threshold] ≤ (project risk appetite) P [project returns ≥ project investment × hurdle rate] ≥ (1-appetite) K K w ( P ) (1 + r ( P ) w ( P ) )(1 + r ( P ) � � P [ ) ≥ ( )] ≥ 1 − α 1 0 i i i i =1 i =1 13 / 33

  10. Introduction Static Risk Appetite Numerical Dynamic Conclusion Project Risk Constraint Project risk concerns the real business part of the firm Project risk: P [projects returns ≤ threshold] ≤ (project risk appetite) P [project returns ≥ project investment × hurdle rate] ≥ (1-appetite) K K w ( P ) (1 + r ( P ) w ( P ) )(1 + r ( P ) � � P [ ) ≥ ( )] ≥ 1 − α 1 0 i i i i =1 i =1 13 / 33

  11. Introduction Static Risk Appetite Numerical Dynamic Conclusion Project Risk Constraint Project risk concerns the real business part of the firm Project risk: P [projects returns ≤ threshold] ≤ (project risk appetite) P [project returns ≥ project investment × hurdle rate] ≥ (1-appetite) K K w ( P ) (1 + r ( P ) w ( P ) )(1 + r ( P ) � � P [ ) ≥ ( )] ≥ 1 − α 1 0 i i i i =1 i =1 13 / 33

  12. Introduction Static Risk Appetite Numerical Dynamic Conclusion Project Risk Constraint Project risk concerns the real business part of the firm Project risk: P [projects returns ≤ threshold] ≤ (project risk appetite) P [project returns ≥ project investment × hurdle rate] ≥ (1-appetite) K K w ( P ) (1 + r ( P ) w ( P ) )(1 + r ( P ) � � P [ ) ≥ ( )] ≥ 1 − α 1 0 i i i i =1 i =1 Select projects so that a pre-determined minimum project return can be secured with certain confidence 13 / 33

  13. Introduction Static Risk Appetite Numerical Dynamic Conclusion Project Risk Constraint Project risk concerns the real business part of the firm Project risk: P [projects returns ≤ threshold] ≤ (project risk appetite) P [project returns ≥ project investment × hurdle rate] ≥ (1-appetite) K K w ( P ) (1 + r ( P ) w ( P ) )(1 + r ( P ) � � P [ ) ≥ ( )] ≥ 1 − α 1 0 i i i i =1 i =1 Select projects so that a pre-determined minimum project return can be secured with certain confidence Selection is governed by project risk appetite α 1 13 / 33

  14. Introduction Static Risk Appetite Numerical Dynamic Conclusion Financial Risk Constraint Different nature of project risk and financial risk 14 / 33

  15. Introduction Static Risk Appetite Numerical Dynamic Conclusion Financial Risk Constraint Different nature of project risk and financial risk Natural hedges 14 / 33

  16. Introduction Static Risk Appetite Numerical Dynamic Conclusion Financial Risk Constraint Different nature of project risk and financial risk Natural hedges Financial risk: P [asset returns ≥ financial investment × hurdle rate] ≥ (1-appetite) N N w ( A ) (1 + r ( A ) w ( A ) )(1 + r ( A ) � � P [ ) ≥ ( )] ≥ 1 − α 2 0 j j j j =1 j =1 14 / 33

  17. Introduction Static Risk Appetite Numerical Dynamic Conclusion Financial Risk Constraint Different nature of project risk and financial risk Natural hedges Financial risk: P [asset returns ≥ financial investment × hurdle rate] ≥ (1-appetite) N N w ( A ) (1 + r ( A ) w ( A ) )(1 + r ( A ) � � P [ ) ≥ ( )] ≥ 1 − α 2 0 j j j j =1 j =1 14 / 33

  18. Introduction Static Risk Appetite Numerical Dynamic Conclusion Financial Risk Constraint Different nature of project risk and financial risk Natural hedges Financial risk: P [asset returns ≥ financial investment × hurdle rate] ≥ (1-appetite) N N w ( A ) (1 + r ( A ) w ( A ) )(1 + r ( A ) � � P [ ) ≥ ( )] ≥ 1 − α 2 0 j j j j =1 j =1 14 / 33

  19. Introduction Static Risk Appetite Numerical Dynamic Conclusion Financial Risk Constraint Different nature of project risk and financial risk Natural hedges Financial risk: P [asset returns ≥ financial investment × hurdle rate] ≥ (1-appetite) N N w ( A ) (1 + r ( A ) w ( A ) )(1 + r ( A ) � � P [ ) ≥ ( )] ≥ 1 − α 2 0 j j j j =1 j =1 Could incorporate hedging policies in the decision framework (e.g., Caldentey and Haugh 2006) 14 / 33

  20. Introduction Static Risk Appetite Numerical Dynamic Conclusion Operational (OP) Risk Constraint “The most important risk category” (Towers and Perrin 2006) 15 / 33

  21. Introduction Static Risk Appetite Numerical Dynamic Conclusion Operational (OP) Risk Constraint “The most important risk category” (Towers and Perrin 2006) Standardized approach in Basel Capital Accord II OP risk = � i (factor i × general indicator in business unit i ) 15 / 33

  22. Introduction Static Risk Appetite Numerical Dynamic Conclusion Operational (OP) Risk Constraint “The most important risk category” (Towers and Perrin 2006) Standardized approach in Basel Capital Accord II OP risk = � i (factor i × general indicator in business unit i ) P [op risk (projects)+op risk (financial) ≤ op risk limit] ≥ (1-appetite) K N w ( P ) (1 + r ( P ) w ( A ) (1 + r ( A ) � � P [ γ 1 ) + γ 2 ) ≤ l op ] ≥ 1 − α 3 i i j j i =1 j =1 15 / 33

  23. Introduction Static Risk Appetite Numerical Dynamic Conclusion Operational (OP) Risk Constraint “The most important risk category” (Towers and Perrin 2006) Standardized approach in Basel Capital Accord II OP risk = � i (factor i × general indicator in business unit i ) P [op risk (projects)+op risk (financial) ≤ op risk limit] ≥ (1-appetite) K N w ( P ) (1 + r ( P ) w ( A ) (1 + r ( A ) � � P [ γ 1 ) + γ 2 ) ≤ l op ] ≥ 1 − α 3 i i j j i =1 j =1 General indicators for each business unit 15 / 33

  24. Introduction Static Risk Appetite Numerical Dynamic Conclusion Operational (OP) Risk Constraint “The most important risk category” (Towers and Perrin 2006) Standardized approach in Basel Capital Accord II OP risk = � i (factor i × general indicator in business unit i ) P [op risk (projects)+op risk (financial) ≤ op risk limit] ≥ (1-appetite) K N w ( P ) (1 + r ( P ) w ( A ) (1 + r ( A ) � � P [ γ 1 ) + γ 2 ) ≤ l op ] ≥ 1 − α 3 i i j j i =1 j =1 General indicators for each business unit Two different factors for each business unit 15 / 33

  25. Introduction Static Risk Appetite Numerical Dynamic Conclusion Operational (OP) Risk Constraint “The most important risk category” (Towers and Perrin 2006) Standardized approach in Basel Capital Accord II OP risk = � i (factor i × general indicator in business unit i ) P [op risk (projects)+op risk (financial) ≤ op risk limit] ≥ (1-appetite) K N w ( P ) (1 + r ( P ) w ( A ) (1 + r ( A ) � � P [ γ 1 ) + γ 2 ) ≤ l op ] ≥ 1 − α 3 i i j j i =1 j =1 General indicators for each business unit Two different factors for each business unit 15 / 33

  26. Introduction Static Risk Appetite Numerical Dynamic Conclusion Operational (OP) Risk Constraint “The most important risk category” (Towers and Perrin 2006) Standardized approach in Basel Capital Accord II OP risk = � i (factor i × general indicator in business unit i ) P [op risk (projects)+op risk (financial) ≤ op risk limit] ≥ (1-appetite) K N w ( P ) (1 + r ( P ) w ( A ) (1 + r ( A ) � � P [ γ 1 ) + γ 2 ) ≤ l op ] ≥ 1 − α 3 i i j j i =1 j =1 General indicators for each business unit Two different factors for each business unit 15 / 33

  27. Introduction Static Risk Appetite Numerical Dynamic Conclusion Operational (OP) Risk Constraint “The most important risk category” (Towers and Perrin 2006) Standardized approach in Basel Capital Accord II OP risk = � i (factor i × general indicator in business unit i ) P [op risk (projects)+op risk (financial) ≤ op risk limit] ≥ (1-appetite) K N w ( P ) (1 + r ( P ) w ( A ) (1 + r ( A ) � � P [ γ 1 ) + γ 2 ) ≤ l op ] ≥ 1 − α 3 i i j j i =1 j =1 General indicators for each business unit Two different factors for each business unit Interactions between project risk and financial risk 15 / 33

  28. Introduction Static Risk Appetite Numerical Dynamic Conclusion Hazard Risk Constraint Mitigate hazard risk by purchasing (costly) insurance One constraint to govern the financial consequences from uninsured proportion of the hazard risk 16 / 33

  29. Introduction Static Risk Appetite Numerical Dynamic Conclusion Hazard Risk Constraint Mitigate hazard risk by purchasing (costly) insurance One constraint to govern the financial consequences from uninsured proportion of the hazard risk Hazard risk: P [uninsured proportion × hazard risk ≤ hazard risk limit] ≥ (1-appetite) P [(1 − u ) l ′ ≤ m ] ≥ 1 − α 4 16 / 33

  30. Introduction Static Risk Appetite Numerical Dynamic Conclusion Hazard Risk Constraint Mitigate hazard risk by purchasing (costly) insurance One constraint to govern the financial consequences from uninsured proportion of the hazard risk Hazard risk: P [uninsured proportion × hazard risk ≤ hazard risk limit] ≥ (1-appetite) P [(1 − u ) l ′ ≤ m ] ≥ 1 − α 4 l ′ = l × (1 + θ ): the unit total hazard loss 16 / 33

  31. Introduction Static Risk Appetite Numerical Dynamic Conclusion Hazard Risk Constraint Mitigate hazard risk by purchasing (costly) insurance One constraint to govern the financial consequences from uninsured proportion of the hazard risk Hazard risk: P [uninsured proportion × hazard risk ≤ hazard risk limit] ≥ (1-appetite) P [(1 − u ) l ′ ≤ m ] ≥ 1 − α 4 l ′ = l × (1 + θ ): the unit total hazard loss u : proportion of total hazard risk insured 16 / 33

  32. Introduction Static Risk Appetite Numerical Dynamic Conclusion Hazard Risk Constraint Mitigate hazard risk by purchasing (costly) insurance One constraint to govern the financial consequences from uninsured proportion of the hazard risk Hazard risk: P [uninsured proportion × hazard risk ≤ hazard risk limit] ≥ (1-appetite) P [(1 − u ) l ′ ≤ m ] ≥ 1 − α 4 l ′ = l × (1 + θ ): the unit total hazard loss u : proportion of total hazard risk insured m : hazard risk limit 16 / 33

  33. Introduction Static Risk Appetite Numerical Dynamic Conclusion Hazard Risk Constraint Mitigate hazard risk by purchasing (costly) insurance One constraint to govern the financial consequences from uninsured proportion of the hazard risk Hazard risk: P [uninsured proportion × hazard risk ≤ hazard risk limit] ≥ (1-appetite) P [(1 − u ) l ′ ≤ m ] ≥ 1 − α 4 l ′ = l × (1 + θ ): the unit total hazard loss u : proportion of total hazard risk insured m : hazard risk limit 16 / 33

  34. Introduction Static Risk Appetite Numerical Dynamic Conclusion Overall Risk Constraint An integration of all risk categories The firm needs to be able to repay the required obligations (when contingent borrowing is not possible) to avoid default 17 / 33

  35. Introduction Static Risk Appetite Numerical Dynamic Conclusion Overall Risk Constraint An integration of all risk categories The firm needs to be able to repay the required obligations (when contingent borrowing is not possible) to avoid default P [(project: returns - op risk)+(financial: returns - op risk) - uninsured hazard risk - insurance ≤ obligation] ≤ (appetite) 17 / 33

  36. Introduction Static Risk Appetite Numerical Dynamic Conclusion Overall Risk Constraint An integration of all risk categories The firm needs to be able to repay the required obligations (when contingent borrowing is not possible) to avoid default P [(project: returns - op risk)+(financial: returns - op risk) - uninsured hazard risk - insurance ≤ obligation] ≤ (appetite) K N w ( P ) (1 + r ( P ) w ( A ) (1 + r ( A ) � � P [(1 − γ 1 ) ) + (1 − γ 2 ) ) i i j j i =1 j =1 − (1 − u ) l ′ − (1 + d ) u (1 + θ ) µ ≤ c ] ≤ ¯ α 17 / 33

  37. Introduction Static Risk Appetite Numerical Dynamic Conclusion Overall Risk Constraint An integration of all risk categories The firm needs to be able to repay the required obligations (when contingent borrowing is not possible) to avoid default P [(project: returns - op risk)+(financial: returns - op risk) - uninsured hazard risk - insurance ≤ obligation] ≤ (appetite) K N w ( P ) (1 + r ( P ) w ( A ) (1 + r ( A ) � � P [(1 − γ 1 ) ) + (1 − γ 2 ) ) i i j j i =1 j =1 − (1 − u ) l ′ − (1 + d ) u (1 + θ ) µ ≤ c ] ≤ ¯ α 17 / 33

  38. Introduction Static Risk Appetite Numerical Dynamic Conclusion Overall Risk Constraint An integration of all risk categories The firm needs to be able to repay the required obligations (when contingent borrowing is not possible) to avoid default P [(project: returns - op risk)+(financial: returns - op risk) - uninsured hazard risk - insurance ≤ obligation] ≤ (appetite) K N w ( P ) (1 + r ( P ) w ( A ) (1 + r ( A ) � � P [(1 − γ 1 ) ) + (1 − γ 2 ) ) i i j j i =1 j =1 − (1 − u ) l ′ − (1 + d ) u (1 + θ ) µ ≤ c ] ≤ ¯ α 17 / 33

  39. Introduction Static Risk Appetite Numerical Dynamic Conclusion Overall Risk Constraint An integration of all risk categories The firm needs to be able to repay the required obligations (when contingent borrowing is not possible) to avoid default P [(project: returns - op risk)+(financial: returns - op risk) - uninsured hazard risk - insurance ≤ obligation] ≤ (appetite) K N w ( P ) (1 + r ( P ) w ( A ) (1 + r ( A ) � � P [(1 − γ 1 ) ) + (1 − γ 2 ) ) i i j j i =1 j =1 − (1 − u ) l ′ − (1 + d ) u (1 + θ ) µ ≤ c ] ≤ ¯ α 17 / 33

  40. Introduction Static Risk Appetite Numerical Dynamic Conclusion Overall Risk Constraint An integration of all risk categories The firm needs to be able to repay the required obligations (when contingent borrowing is not possible) to avoid default P [(project: returns - op risk)+(financial: returns - op risk) - uninsured hazard risk - insurance ≤ obligation] ≤ (appetite) K N w ( P ) (1 + r ( P ) w ( A ) (1 + r ( A ) � � P [(1 − γ 1 ) ) + (1 − γ 2 ) ) i i j j i =1 j =1 − (1 − u ) l ′ − (1 + d ) u (1 + θ ) µ ≤ c ] ≤ ¯ α 17 / 33

  41. Introduction Static Risk Appetite Numerical Dynamic Conclusion Overall Risk Constraint An integration of all risk categories The firm needs to be able to repay the required obligations (when contingent borrowing is not possible) to avoid default P [(project: returns - op risk)+(financial: returns - op risk) - uninsured hazard risk - insurance ≤ obligation] ≤ (appetite) K N w ( P ) (1 + r ( P ) w ( A ) (1 + r ( A ) � � P [(1 − γ 1 ) ) + (1 − γ 2 ) ) i i j j i =1 j =1 − (1 − u ) l ′ − (1 + d ) u (1 + θ ) µ ≤ c ] ≤ ¯ α 17 / 33

  42. Introduction Static Risk Appetite Numerical Dynamic Conclusion Overall Risk Constraint An integration of all risk categories The firm needs to be able to repay the required obligations (when contingent borrowing is not possible) to avoid default P [(project: returns - op risk)+(financial: returns - op risk) - uninsured hazard risk - insurance ≤ obligation] ≤ (appetite) K N w ( P ) (1 + r ( P ) w ( A ) (1 + r ( A ) � � P [(1 − γ 1 ) ) + (1 − γ 2 ) ) i i j j i =1 j =1 − (1 − u ) l ′ − (1 + d ) u (1 + θ ) µ ≤ c ] ≤ ¯ α 17 / 33

  43. Introduction Static Risk Appetite Numerical Dynamic Conclusion Deterministic Constraints Budget constraint: K N w ( P ) w ( A ) � � + + u (1 + d )(1 + θ ) µ ≤ 1 i j i =1 j =1 Strategic constraint: K w ( P ) � ≥ γ 3 i i =1 Range constraints: w ( P ) ≥ 0 , w ( A ) ≥ 0 , 0 ≤ ν ≤ 1 i j 18 / 33

  44. Introduction Static Risk Appetite Numerical Dynamic Conclusion The ERM Framework max E[project returns + financial returns - insurance] w ( P ) , w ( A ) , u i j s.t. P [project returns ≥ hurdle rate] ≥ (1- α 1 ) P [financial returns ≥ hurdle rate] ≥ (1- α 2 ) P [op risk ≤ risk limit] ≤ α 3 P [uninsured hazard risk ≤ risk limit] ≤ α 4 P [total returns - all risk - insurance ≤ obligation] ≤ ¯ α budget constraint, strategic constraint, range constraints 19 / 33

  45. Introduction Static Risk Appetite Numerical Dynamic Conclusion The ERM Framework max E[project returns + financial returns - insurance] w ( P ) , w ( A ) , u i j s.t. P [project returns ≥ hurdle rate] ≥ (1- α 1 ) P [financial returns ≥ hurdle rate] ≥ (1- α 2 ) P [op risk ≤ risk limit] ≤ α 3 P [uninsured hazard risk ≤ risk limit] ≤ α 4 P [total returns - all risk - insurance ≤ obligation] ≤ ¯ α budget constraint, strategic constraint, range constraints 19 / 33

  46. Introduction Static Risk Appetite Numerical Dynamic Conclusion The ERM Framework max E[project returns + financial returns - insurance] w ( P ) , w ( A ) , u i j s.t. P [project returns ≥ hurdle rate] ≥ (1- α 1 ) P [financial returns ≥ hurdle rate] ≥ (1- α 2 ) P [op risk ≤ risk limit] ≤ α 3 P [uninsured hazard risk ≤ risk limit] ≤ α 4 P [total returns - all risk - insurance ≤ obligation] ≤ ¯ α budget constraint, strategic constraint, range constraints 19 / 33

  47. Introduction Static Risk Appetite Numerical Dynamic Conclusion Computation of the Constraint Set To convert from the VaR type risk constraint to a deterministic constraint for use in mathematical programming, we use the fact that if P [ X ≥ t ] ≥ 1 − α then t ≤ F − 1 ( α ) 20 / 33

  48. Introduction Static Risk Appetite Numerical Dynamic Conclusion Computation of the Constraint Set To convert from the VaR type risk constraint to a deterministic constraint for use in mathematical programming, we use the fact that if P [ X ≥ t ] ≥ 1 − α then t ≤ F − 1 ( α ) So for example the financial risk constraint N N � w ( A ) (1 + r ( A ) � w ( A ) )(1 + r ( A ) P [ ) ≥ ( )] ≥ 1 − α 2 j j j 0 j =1 j =1 becocmes � (1+ r ( A ) )( W ( A ) ) T ι − ( W ( A ) ) T ( ι + E ( r ) ( A ) ) ≤ Φ − 1 ( α 2 ) ( W ( A ) ) T Σ ( A ) W ( A ) 0 20 / 33

  49. Introduction Static Risk Appetite Numerical Dynamic Conclusion Risk Appetite The firm should articulate how risk appetite falls in line with strategic goals and risk culture (S&P 2005) 21 / 33

  50. Introduction Static Risk Appetite Numerical Dynamic Conclusion Risk Appetite The firm should articulate how risk appetite falls in line with strategic goals and risk culture (S&P 2005) Determine risk appetite in light of the credit rating target (Nocco and Stulz 2006) 21 / 33

  51. Introduction Static Risk Appetite Numerical Dynamic Conclusion Risk Appetite The firm should articulate how risk appetite falls in line with strategic goals and risk culture (S&P 2005) Determine risk appetite in light of the credit rating target (Nocco and Stulz 2006) Strategic goals govern the risk appetite 21 / 33

  52. Introduction Static Risk Appetite Numerical Dynamic Conclusion Risk Appetite The firm should articulate how risk appetite falls in line with strategic goals and risk culture (S&P 2005) Determine risk appetite in light of the credit rating target (Nocco and Stulz 2006) Strategic goals govern the risk appetite Credit rating target proxies for the firm’s strategic goals 21 / 33

  53. Introduction Static Risk Appetite Numerical Dynamic Conclusion Risk Appetite The firm should articulate how risk appetite falls in line with strategic goals and risk culture (S&P 2005) Determine risk appetite in light of the credit rating target (Nocco and Stulz 2006) Strategic goals govern the risk appetite Credit rating target proxies for the firm’s strategic goals determines the ability to raise capital and the cost of capital (West 1973) influences corporate policies and actual business strategies (Sufi 2007) 21 / 33

  54. A 0.01% 1.32% 90.71% 6.92% 0.75% 0.19% 0.04% 0.06% 0.00% A 0.08% 3.02% 90.24% 5.67% 0.76% Aa 0.00% 0.03% B Rating From: Aaa Aa Source: Moody’s Default and Recovery Rates of Corporate Bond Issuers, 1920-2005, March 2006. Baa Ba Caa-C 0.00% Default Aaa 91.75% 7.26% 0.79% 0.17% 0.02% 0.12% 0.08% 4.78% 0.07% 0.20% 0.80% 7.29% 80.62% 6.23% Caa-C B 0.00% 0.03% 0.06% 0.23% 1.07% 7.69% 75.24% 0.00% 1.48% Baa 0.18% 0.05% 0.33% 5.05% 87.50% 5.72% 0.86% 0.31% 0.72% Ba 0.01% 0.09% 0.59% 6.70% 82.58% 7.83% Rating To: Table 1 Transition Matrix from Moody’s Average one-year rating transition matrix, 1920-2005, conditional upon no rating withdrawal. to฀average฀around฀7%.฀To฀determine฀the฀probability฀of฀a฀ beginning฀ of฀ the฀ year฀ (listed฀ in฀ the฀ left-hand฀ column฀ of฀ the฀table),฀the฀column฀of฀numbers฀running฀down฀from฀the฀ heading฀“Baa”฀tells฀us฀the฀probability฀that฀a฀company฀will฀ end฀up฀with฀a฀Baa฀rating฀at฀the฀end฀of฀the฀year. Again,฀ let’s฀ assume฀ management฀ wants฀ the฀ probabil- ity฀of฀its฀rating฀falling฀to฀Baa฀or฀lower฀over฀the฀next฀year฀ downgrade฀to฀or฀lower฀than฀Baa฀for฀a฀given฀initial฀rating,฀ companies฀moved฀from฀one฀rating฀to฀another฀over฀a฀certain฀ we฀add฀up฀the฀probabilities฀of฀ending฀with฀a฀rating฀equal฀ to฀or฀lower฀than฀Baa฀along฀the฀row฀that฀corresponds฀to฀the฀ initial฀rating.฀The฀row฀where฀the฀probabilities฀of฀ending฀at฀ Baa฀or฀lower฀is฀closest฀to฀7%฀is฀the฀one฀corresponding฀to฀an฀ A฀rating.฀Consequently,฀by฀targeting฀an฀A฀rating,฀manage- ment฀would฀achieve฀the฀probability฀of฀financial฀distress฀that฀ is฀optimal฀for฀the฀firm.฀ period฀(in฀this฀case,฀1920฀to฀2005). 7 ฀For฀any฀rating฀at฀the฀ in฀Table฀1฀can฀be฀used฀to฀identify฀the฀frequency฀with฀which฀ rating฀ can฀ involve฀ more฀ considerations,฀ which฀ makes฀ it฀ A Morgan Stanley Publication • Fall 2006 standing when the firm has long-term debt. default. So, the default threshold level is lower than the principal amount of debt out- firm value could fall below the principal amount of debt outstanding without triggering a principal amount of debt outstanding plus interest due. However, if debt matures later, 8. If all debt were due at the end of the year, the default threshold level would be the 7. See footnote 2. Journal of Applied Corporate Finance • Volume 18 Number 4 support฀a฀given฀level฀of฀risk.฀The฀transition฀matrix฀shown฀ 12 of฀risk฀would฀be฀determined฀by฀comparing฀the฀costs฀associ- ated฀with฀financial฀distress฀and฀the฀benefits฀of฀having฀a฀more฀ levered฀capital฀structure฀and฀taking฀on฀riskier฀projects.฀ To฀the฀extent฀that฀ratings฀are฀reliable฀proxies฀for฀finan- cial฀health,฀companies฀can฀use฀a฀rating฀agency฀“transition฀ matrix”฀ to฀ estimate฀ the฀ amount฀ of฀ capital฀ necessary฀ to฀ In฀practice,฀however,฀the฀process฀of฀determining฀a฀target฀ more฀complicated.฀For฀example,฀Nationwide฀analyzes฀and฀ falling฀below฀the฀default฀threshold฀level฀equal฀to฀0.08%฀ cated฀ function฀ of฀ a฀ number฀ of฀ firm฀ characteristics,฀ not฀ bility฀of฀default฀equal฀to฀0.08%.฀If฀we฀make฀the฀assumption฀ that฀ the฀ value฀ of฀ a฀ company’s฀ equity฀ falls฀ to฀ a฀ level฀ not฀ materially฀different฀from฀zero฀in฀the฀event฀of฀default,฀we฀ can฀use฀the฀probability฀of฀default฀to฀“back฀out”฀the฀amount฀ of฀equity฀the฀firm฀needs฀to฀support฀its฀current฀level฀of฀risk. Although฀the฀probability฀of฀default฀is฀in฀fact฀a฀compli- just฀the฀amount฀of฀equity,฀the฀analytical฀process฀that฀leads฀ Thus,฀to฀achieve฀an฀A฀rating,฀the฀company฀in฀our฀example฀ from฀the฀probability฀of฀default฀to฀the฀required฀amount฀of฀ capital฀ is฀ straightforward.฀ To฀ see฀ this,฀ suppose฀ that฀ the฀ company฀ becomes฀ bankrupt฀ if฀ firm฀ value฀ at฀ the฀ end฀ of฀ the฀fiscal฀year฀falls฀below฀a฀default฀threshold฀level,฀which฀ is฀a฀function฀of฀the฀composition฀and฀amount฀of฀the฀firm’s฀ debt. 8 ฀Given฀this฀assumption,฀the฀firm฀needs฀the฀amount฀ of฀equity฀capital฀that฀will฀make฀the฀probability฀of฀its฀value฀ must฀have฀the฀level฀of฀(equity)฀capital฀that฀makes฀its฀proba- a฀probability฀of฀default฀of฀0.08%฀over฀a฀one-year฀period.฀ manages฀both฀its฀probability฀of฀default฀and฀its฀probability฀of฀ arising฀from฀natural฀catastrophes฀and฀equity฀markets. downgrade,฀and฀it฀does฀so฀in฀separate฀but฀related฀frameworks.฀ The฀company’s฀optimal฀probability฀of฀default฀is฀anchored฀to฀ its฀target฀Aa฀ratings฀and฀reflects฀the฀default฀history฀of฀Aa- rated฀bonds.฀By฀contrast,฀the฀probability฀of฀downgrade฀to฀ Baa฀or฀below฀is฀assumed฀to฀be฀affected฀by,฀and฀is฀accord- ingly฀managed฀by฀limiting,฀risk฀concentrations฀such฀as฀those฀ In฀ the฀ example฀ above,฀ the฀ company฀ is฀ assumed฀ to฀ As฀can฀be฀seen฀in฀Table฀1,฀an฀A฀rating฀is฀associated฀with฀ maximize฀ value฀ by฀ targeting฀ a฀ rating฀ of฀ A.฀ As฀ we฀ noted฀ earlier,฀equity฀capital฀provides฀a฀buffer฀or฀shock฀absorber฀ that฀ helps฀ the฀ firm฀ to฀ avoid฀ default.฀ For฀ a฀ given฀ firm,฀ a฀ different฀probability฀of฀default฀corresponds฀to฀each฀level฀of฀ equity,฀so฀that฀by฀choosing฀a฀given฀level฀of฀equity,฀manage- ment฀is฀also฀effectively฀choosing฀a฀probability฀of฀default฀that฀ it฀believes฀to฀be฀optimal. 15.69% Introduction Static Risk Appetite Numerical Dynamic Conclusion Choice of Risk Appetite Overall risk appetite parameter (¯ α ) target default probability implied by the credit rating target used in the overall risk constraint 22 / 33

  55. Aaa 6.92% 0.00% 0.00% 0.00% Aa 1.32% 90.71% 0.75% 0.17% 0.19% 0.04% 0.01% 0.06% A 0.08% 0.02% 0.79% 90.24% Aa falling฀below฀the฀default฀threshold฀level฀equal฀to฀0.08%฀ Table 1 Transition Matrix from Moody’s Rating To: Rating From: 7.69% A 7.26% Baa Ba B Caa-C Default Aaa 91.75% 3.02% 5.67% debt. 8 ฀Given฀this฀assumption,฀the฀firm฀needs฀the฀amount฀ 0.80% 0.72% 1.48% B 0.00% 0.07% 0.20% 7.29% 82.58% 80.62% 6.23% 4.78% Caa-C 0.00% 0.03% 0.06% 7.83% 6.70% 0.76% 5.05% 0.12% 0.03% 0.08% Baa 0.05% 0.33% 87.50% 0.59% 5.72% 0.86% 0.18% 0.31% Ba 0.01% 0.09% of฀equity฀capital฀that฀will฀make฀the฀probability฀of฀its฀value฀ is฀a฀function฀of฀the฀composition฀and฀amount฀of฀the฀firm’s฀ 1.07% heading฀“Baa”฀tells฀us฀the฀probability฀that฀a฀company฀will฀ support฀a฀given฀level฀of฀risk.฀The฀transition฀matrix฀shown฀ in฀Table฀1฀can฀be฀used฀to฀identify฀the฀frequency฀with฀which฀ companies฀moved฀from฀one฀rating฀to฀another฀over฀a฀certain฀ period฀(in฀this฀case,฀1920฀to฀2005). 7 ฀For฀any฀rating฀at฀the฀ beginning฀ of฀ the฀ year฀ (listed฀ in฀ the฀ left-hand฀ column฀ of฀ the฀table),฀the฀column฀of฀numbers฀running฀down฀from฀the฀ end฀up฀with฀a฀Baa฀rating฀at฀the฀end฀of฀the฀year. cial฀health,฀companies฀can฀use฀a฀rating฀agency฀“transition฀ Again,฀ let’s฀ assume฀ management฀ wants฀ the฀ probabil- ity฀of฀its฀rating฀falling฀to฀Baa฀or฀lower฀over฀the฀next฀year฀ to฀average฀around฀7%.฀To฀determine฀the฀probability฀of฀a฀ downgrade฀to฀or฀lower฀than฀Baa฀for฀a฀given฀initial฀rating,฀ we฀add฀up฀the฀probabilities฀of฀ending฀with฀a฀rating฀equal฀ to฀or฀lower฀than฀Baa฀along฀the฀row฀that฀corresponds฀to฀the฀ initial฀rating.฀The฀row฀where฀the฀probabilities฀of฀ending฀at฀ matrix”฀ to฀ estimate฀ the฀ amount฀ of฀ capital฀ necessary฀ to฀ To฀the฀extent฀that฀ratings฀are฀reliable฀proxies฀for฀finan- A฀rating.฀Consequently,฀by฀targeting฀an฀A฀rating,฀manage- A Morgan Stanley Publication • Fall 2006 standing when the firm has long-term debt. default. So, the default threshold level is lower than the principal amount of debt out- firm value could fall below the principal amount of debt outstanding without triggering a principal amount of debt outstanding plus interest due. However, if debt matures later, 8. If all debt were due at the end of the year, the default threshold level would be the 7. See footnote 2. Journal of Applied Corporate Finance • Volume 18 Number 4 levered฀capital฀structure฀and฀taking฀on฀riskier฀projects.฀ 12 Source: Moody’s Default and Recovery Rates of Corporate Bond Issuers, 1920-2005, March 2006. Average one-year rating transition matrix, 1920-2005, conditional upon no rating withdrawal. 15.69% 75.24% of฀risk฀would฀be฀determined฀by฀comparing฀the฀costs฀associ- ated฀with฀financial฀distress฀and฀the฀benefits฀of฀having฀a฀more฀ Baa฀or฀lower฀is฀closest฀to฀7%฀is฀the฀one฀corresponding฀to฀an฀ ment฀would฀achieve฀the฀probability฀of฀financial฀distress฀that฀ the฀fiscal฀year฀falls฀below฀a฀default฀threshold฀level,฀which฀ materially฀different฀from฀zero฀in฀the฀event฀of฀default,฀we฀ As฀can฀be฀seen฀in฀Table฀1,฀an฀A฀rating฀is฀associated฀with฀ a฀probability฀of฀default฀of฀0.08%฀over฀a฀one-year฀period.฀ Thus,฀to฀achieve฀an฀A฀rating,฀the฀company฀in฀our฀example฀ must฀have฀the฀level฀of฀(equity)฀capital฀that฀makes฀its฀proba- bility฀of฀default฀equal฀to฀0.08%.฀If฀we฀make฀the฀assumption฀ that฀ the฀ value฀ of฀ a฀ company’s฀ equity฀ falls฀ to฀ a฀ level฀ not฀ can฀use฀the฀probability฀of฀default฀to฀“back฀out”฀the฀amount฀ ment฀is฀also฀effectively฀choosing฀a฀probability฀of฀default฀that฀ of฀equity฀the฀firm฀needs฀to฀support฀its฀current฀level฀of฀risk. Although฀the฀probability฀of฀default฀is฀in฀fact฀a฀compli- cated฀ function฀ of฀ a฀ number฀ of฀ firm฀ characteristics,฀ not฀ just฀the฀amount฀of฀equity,฀the฀analytical฀process฀that฀leads฀ from฀the฀probability฀of฀default฀to฀the฀required฀amount฀of฀ capital฀ is฀ straightforward.฀ To฀ see฀ this,฀ suppose฀ that฀ the฀ company฀ becomes฀ bankrupt฀ if฀ firm฀ value฀ at฀ the฀ end฀ of฀ it฀believes฀to฀be฀optimal. equity,฀so฀that฀by฀choosing฀a฀given฀level฀of฀equity,฀manage- is฀optimal฀for฀the฀firm.฀ its฀target฀Aa฀ratings฀and฀reflects฀the฀default฀history฀of฀Aa- In฀practice,฀however,฀the฀process฀of฀determining฀a฀target฀ rating฀ can฀ involve฀ more฀ considerations,฀ which฀ makes฀ it฀ more฀complicated.฀For฀example,฀Nationwide฀analyzes฀and฀ manages฀both฀its฀probability฀of฀default฀and฀its฀probability฀of฀ downgrade,฀and฀it฀does฀so฀in฀separate฀but฀related฀frameworks.฀ The฀company’s฀optimal฀probability฀of฀default฀is฀anchored฀to฀ rated฀bonds.฀By฀contrast,฀the฀probability฀of฀downgrade฀to฀ different฀probability฀of฀default฀corresponds฀to฀each฀level฀of฀ Baa฀or฀below฀is฀assumed฀to฀be฀affected฀by,฀and฀is฀accord- ingly฀managed฀by฀limiting,฀risk฀concentrations฀such฀as฀those฀ arising฀from฀natural฀catastrophes฀and฀equity฀markets. In฀ the฀ example฀ above,฀ the฀ company฀ is฀ assumed฀ to฀ maximize฀ value฀ by฀ targeting฀ a฀ rating฀ of฀ A.฀ As฀ we฀ noted฀ earlier,฀equity฀capital฀provides฀a฀buffer฀or฀shock฀absorber฀ that฀ helps฀ the฀ firm฀ to฀ avoid฀ default.฀ For฀ a฀ given฀ firm,฀ a฀ 0.23% Introduction Static Risk Appetite Numerical Dynamic Conclusion Choice of Risk Appetite Overall risk appetite parameter (¯ α ) target default probability implied by the credit rating target used in the overall risk constraint Individual risk appetite parameters ( α ′ i s ) different appetites toward different risks reference point: financial distress probability 22 / 33

  56. Aaa 90.71% 0.02% 0.00% 0.00% 0.00% Aa 1.32% 6.92% 0.79% 0.75% 0.19% 0.04% 0.01% 0.06% A 0.17% 7.26% 3.02% 1.07% of฀equity฀capital฀that฀will฀make฀the฀probability฀of฀its฀value฀ falling฀below฀the฀default฀threshold฀level฀equal฀to฀0.08%฀ Table 1 Transition Matrix from Moody’s Rating To: Rating From: Aa 91.75% A Baa Ba B Caa-C Default Aaa 0.08% 90.24% is฀a฀function฀of฀the฀composition฀and฀amount฀of฀the฀firm’s฀ 0.20% 7.83% 0.72% 1.48% B 0.00% 0.07% 0.80% 6.70% 7.29% 80.62% 6.23% 4.78% Caa-C 0.00% 0.03% 82.58% 0.59% 5.67% 0.33% 0.76% 0.12% 0.03% 0.08% Baa 0.05% 5.05% 0.09% 87.50% 5.72% 0.86% 0.18% 0.31% Ba 0.01% debt. 8 ฀Given฀this฀assumption,฀the฀firm฀needs฀the฀amount฀ the฀fiscal฀year฀falls฀below฀a฀default฀threshold฀level,฀which฀ 0.23% the฀table),฀the฀column฀of฀numbers฀running฀down฀from฀the฀ matrix”฀ to฀ estimate฀ the฀ amount฀ of฀ capital฀ necessary฀ to฀ support฀a฀given฀level฀of฀risk.฀The฀transition฀matrix฀shown฀ in฀Table฀1฀can฀be฀used฀to฀identify฀the฀frequency฀with฀which฀ companies฀moved฀from฀one฀rating฀to฀another฀over฀a฀certain฀ period฀(in฀this฀case,฀1920฀to฀2005). 7 ฀For฀any฀rating฀at฀the฀ beginning฀ of฀ the฀ year฀ (listed฀ in฀ the฀ left-hand฀ column฀ of฀ heading฀“Baa”฀tells฀us฀the฀probability฀that฀a฀company฀will฀ To฀the฀extent฀that฀ratings฀are฀reliable฀proxies฀for฀finan- end฀up฀with฀a฀Baa฀rating฀at฀the฀end฀of฀the฀year. Again,฀ let’s฀ assume฀ management฀ wants฀ the฀ probabil- ity฀of฀its฀rating฀falling฀to฀Baa฀or฀lower฀over฀the฀next฀year฀ to฀average฀around฀7%.฀To฀determine฀the฀probability฀of฀a฀ downgrade฀to฀or฀lower฀than฀Baa฀for฀a฀given฀initial฀rating,฀ we฀add฀up฀the฀probabilities฀of฀ending฀with฀a฀rating฀equal฀ to฀or฀lower฀than฀Baa฀along฀the฀row฀that฀corresponds฀to฀the฀ cial฀health,฀companies฀can฀use฀a฀rating฀agency฀“transition฀ levered฀capital฀structure฀and฀taking฀on฀riskier฀projects.฀ Baa฀or฀lower฀is฀closest฀to฀7%฀is฀the฀one฀corresponding฀to฀an฀ A Morgan Stanley Publication • Fall 2006 standing when the firm has long-term debt. default. So, the default threshold level is lower than the principal amount of debt out- firm value could fall below the principal amount of debt outstanding without triggering a principal amount of debt outstanding plus interest due. However, if debt matures later, 8. If all debt were due at the end of the year, the default threshold level would be the 7. See footnote 2. Journal of Applied Corporate Finance • Volume 18 Number 4 ated฀with฀financial฀distress฀and฀the฀benefits฀of฀having฀a฀more฀ 12 Source: Moody’s Default and Recovery Rates of Corporate Bond Issuers, 1920-2005, March 2006. Average one-year rating transition matrix, 1920-2005, conditional upon no rating withdrawal. 15.69% 75.24% 7.69% of฀risk฀would฀be฀determined฀by฀comparing฀the฀costs฀associ- initial฀rating.฀The฀row฀where฀the฀probabilities฀of฀ending฀at฀ A฀rating.฀Consequently,฀by฀targeting฀an฀A฀rating,฀manage- company฀ becomes฀ bankrupt฀ if฀ firm฀ value฀ at฀ the฀ end฀ of฀ that฀ the฀ value฀ of฀ a฀ company’s฀ equity฀ falls฀ to฀ a฀ level฀ not฀ it฀believes฀to฀be฀optimal. As฀can฀be฀seen฀in฀Table฀1,฀an฀A฀rating฀is฀associated฀with฀ a฀probability฀of฀default฀of฀0.08%฀over฀a฀one-year฀period.฀ Thus,฀to฀achieve฀an฀A฀rating,฀the฀company฀in฀our฀example฀ must฀have฀the฀level฀of฀(equity)฀capital฀that฀makes฀its฀proba- bility฀of฀default฀equal฀to฀0.08%.฀If฀we฀make฀the฀assumption฀ materially฀different฀from฀zero฀in฀the฀event฀of฀default,฀we฀ equity,฀so฀that฀by฀choosing฀a฀given฀level฀of฀equity,฀manage- can฀use฀the฀probability฀of฀default฀to฀“back฀out”฀the฀amount฀ of฀equity฀the฀firm฀needs฀to฀support฀its฀current฀level฀of฀risk. Although฀the฀probability฀of฀default฀is฀in฀fact฀a฀compli- cated฀ function฀ of฀ a฀ number฀ of฀ firm฀ characteristics,฀ not฀ just฀the฀amount฀of฀equity,฀the฀analytical฀process฀that฀leads฀ from฀the฀probability฀of฀default฀to฀the฀required฀amount฀of฀ capital฀ is฀ straightforward.฀ To฀ see฀ this,฀ suppose฀ that฀ the฀ ment฀is฀also฀effectively฀choosing฀a฀probability฀of฀default฀that฀ different฀probability฀of฀default฀corresponds฀to฀each฀level฀of฀ ment฀would฀achieve฀the฀probability฀of฀financial฀distress฀that฀ The฀company’s฀optimal฀probability฀of฀default฀is฀anchored฀to฀ is฀optimal฀for฀the฀firm.฀ In฀practice,฀however,฀the฀process฀of฀determining฀a฀target฀ rating฀ can฀ involve฀ more฀ considerations,฀ which฀ makes฀ it฀ more฀complicated.฀For฀example,฀Nationwide฀analyzes฀and฀ manages฀both฀its฀probability฀of฀default฀and฀its฀probability฀of฀ downgrade,฀and฀it฀does฀so฀in฀separate฀but฀related฀frameworks.฀ its฀target฀Aa฀ratings฀and฀reflects฀the฀default฀history฀of฀Aa- that฀ helps฀ the฀ firm฀ to฀ avoid฀ default.฀ For฀ a฀ given฀ firm,฀ a฀ rated฀bonds.฀By฀contrast,฀the฀probability฀of฀downgrade฀to฀ Baa฀or฀below฀is฀assumed฀to฀be฀affected฀by,฀and฀is฀accord- ingly฀managed฀by฀limiting,฀risk฀concentrations฀such฀as฀those฀ arising฀from฀natural฀catastrophes฀and฀equity฀markets. In฀ the฀ example฀ above,฀ the฀ company฀ is฀ assumed฀ to฀ maximize฀ value฀ by฀ targeting฀ a฀ rating฀ of฀ A.฀ As฀ we฀ noted฀ earlier,฀equity฀capital฀provides฀a฀buffer฀or฀shock฀absorber฀ 0.06% Introduction Static Risk Appetite Numerical Dynamic Conclusion Choice of Risk Appetite Overall risk appetite parameter (¯ α ) target default probability implied by the credit rating target used in the overall risk constraint Individual risk appetite parameters ( α ′ i s ) different appetites toward different risks reference point: financial distress probability Moody’s Rate Transition Matrix Source: Nocco and Stulz. 2006. Enterprise Risk Management Theory and Practice. J. Corp. Fin. 22 / 33

  57. Introduction Static Risk Appetite Numerical Dynamic Conclusion Choice of Risk Appetite Overall risk appetite parameter (¯ α ) target default probability implied by the credit rating target used in the overall risk constraint Individual risk appetite parameters ( α ′ i s ) different appetites toward different risks reference point: financial distress probability 23 / 33

  58. Introduction Static Risk Appetite Numerical Dynamic Conclusion Choice of Risk Appetite Overall risk appetite parameter (¯ α ) target default probability implied by the credit rating target used in the overall risk constraint Individual risk appetite parameters ( α ′ i s ) different appetites toward different risks reference point: financial distress probability Risk Prioritization Individual risk appetite parameters facilitate the quantification of risk prioritization decisions: 23 / 33

  59. Introduction Static Risk Appetite Numerical Dynamic Conclusion Choice of Risk Appetite Overall risk appetite parameter (¯ α ) target default probability implied by the credit rating target used in the overall risk constraint Individual risk appetite parameters ( α ′ i s ) different appetites toward different risks reference point: financial distress probability Risk Prioritization Individual risk appetite parameters facilitate the quantification of risk prioritization decisions: smaller value indicates higher priority of the risk 23 / 33

  60. Introduction Static Risk Appetite Numerical Dynamic Conclusion Numerical Example: Baseline Setting I Purposes Demonstrate how to implement the framework Demonstrate how to determine risk appetite parameters 24 / 33

  61. Introduction Static Risk Appetite Numerical Dynamic Conclusion Numerical Example: Baseline Setting I Purposes Demonstrate how to implement the framework Demonstrate how to determine risk appetite parameters Distributional assumptions � ( E ( r ( P ) ) : E ( r ( A ) )) T , � ( PA ) � Returns r ( P ) and r ( A ) : N i j 24 / 33

  62. Introduction Static Risk Appetite Numerical Dynamic Conclusion Numerical Example: Baseline Setting I Purposes Demonstrate how to implement the framework Demonstrate how to determine risk appetite parameters Distributional assumptions � ( E ( r ( P ) ) : E ( r ( A ) )) T , � ( PA ) � Returns r ( P ) and r ( A ) : N i j Unit total losses from hazard risk l ′ ∼ N ((1 + θ ) µ, (1 + θ ) 2 σ 2 ), 0 < µ < 1, σ > 0 24 / 33

  63. Introduction Static Risk Appetite Numerical Dynamic Conclusion Numerical Example: Baseline Setting I Purposes Demonstrate how to implement the framework Demonstrate how to determine risk appetite parameters Distributional assumptions � ( E ( r ( P ) ) : E ( r ( A ) )) T , � ( PA ) � Returns r ( P ) and r ( A ) : N i j Unit total losses from hazard risk l ′ ∼ N ((1 + θ ) µ, (1 + θ ) 2 σ 2 ), 0 < µ < 1, σ > 0 Hazard risk is independent of the other risk categories 24 / 33

  64. Introduction Static Risk Appetite Numerical Dynamic Conclusion Numerical Example: Baseline Setting II Description of investment opportunities Expected Return and Variance R&D Project Manufacturing Project Index Fund 3 Month T-Bill Expected return 0.3 0.1 0.12 0.038 Variance 0.3 0.003 0.03 0.00025 Correlation of the investments R&D Project Manufacturing Project Index Fund 3 Month T-Bill R&D Project 1 0.1 0.05 -0.05 Manufacturing Project 0.1 1 0.05 -0.05 Index Fund 1 -0.1 3 Month T-Bill 1 25 / 33

  65. ( ) ( ) α α α α α γ γ γ μ σ θ Baa 5.67% 0.76% 0.12% 0.03% 0.08% 87.50% 0.05% 0.33% 5.05% 5.72% 3.02% 0.86% 0.18% 90.24% 0.75% 0.08% Aa 0.79% 0.17% 0.02% 0.00% 0.00% 0.00% 1.32% A 90.71% 6.92% Ba 0.19% 0.04% 0.01% 0.06% 0.31% 0.72% 0.01% 12 1.07% 7.69% 75.24% 15.69% Average one-year rating transition matrix, 1920-2005, conditional upon no rating withdrawal. Source: Moody’s Default and Recovery Rates of Corporate Bond Issuers, 1920-2005, March 2006. Journal of Applied Corporate Finance • Volume 18 Number 4 0.06% A Morgan Stanley Publication • Fall 2006 7. See footnote 2. 8. If all debt were due at the end of the year, the default threshold level would be the principal amount of debt outstanding plus interest due. However, if debt matures later, firm value could fall below the principal amount of debt outstanding without triggering a default. So, the default threshold level is lower than the principal amount of debt out- standing when the firm has long-term debt. 0.23% 0.03% 0.09% 0.00% 0.59% 6.70% 82.58% 7.83% 1.48% B 0.07% 0.00% 0.20% 0.80% 7.29% 80.62% 6.23% 4.78% Caa-C 7.26% 91.75% Aaa rating฀ can฀ involve฀ more฀ considerations,฀ which฀ makes฀ it฀ initial฀rating.฀The฀row฀where฀the฀probabilities฀of฀ending฀at฀ Baa฀or฀lower฀is฀closest฀to฀7%฀is฀the฀one฀corresponding฀to฀an฀ A฀rating.฀Consequently,฀by฀targeting฀an฀A฀rating,฀manage- ment฀would฀achieve฀the฀probability฀of฀financial฀distress฀that฀ is฀optimal฀for฀the฀firm.฀ In฀practice,฀however,฀the฀process฀of฀determining฀a฀target฀ more฀complicated.฀For฀example,฀Nationwide฀analyzes฀and฀ we฀add฀up฀the฀probabilities฀of฀ending฀with฀a฀rating฀equal฀ manages฀both฀its฀probability฀of฀default฀and฀its฀probability฀of฀ downgrade,฀and฀it฀does฀so฀in฀separate฀but฀related฀frameworks.฀ The฀company’s฀optimal฀probability฀of฀default฀is฀anchored฀to฀ its฀target฀Aa฀ratings฀and฀reflects฀the฀default฀history฀of฀Aa- rated฀bonds.฀By฀contrast,฀the฀probability฀of฀downgrade฀to฀ Baa฀or฀below฀is฀assumed฀to฀be฀affected฀by,฀and฀is฀accord- ingly฀managed฀by฀limiting,฀risk฀concentrations฀such฀as฀those฀ to฀or฀lower฀than฀Baa฀along฀the฀row฀that฀corresponds฀to฀the฀ downgrade฀to฀or฀lower฀than฀Baa฀for฀a฀given฀initial฀rating,฀ In฀ the฀ example฀ above,฀ the฀ company฀ is฀ assumed฀ to฀ in฀Table฀1฀can฀be฀used฀to฀identify฀the฀frequency฀with฀which฀ of฀risk฀would฀be฀determined฀by฀comparing฀the฀costs฀associ- ated฀with฀financial฀distress฀and฀the฀benefits฀of฀having฀a฀more฀ levered฀capital฀structure฀and฀taking฀on฀riskier฀projects.฀ To฀the฀extent฀that฀ratings฀are฀reliable฀proxies฀for฀finan- cial฀health,฀companies฀can฀use฀a฀rating฀agency฀“transition฀ matrix”฀ to฀ estimate฀ the฀ amount฀ of฀ capital฀ necessary฀ to฀ support฀a฀given฀level฀of฀risk.฀The฀transition฀matrix฀shown฀ companies฀moved฀from฀one฀rating฀to฀another฀over฀a฀certain฀ to฀average฀around฀7%.฀To฀determine฀the฀probability฀of฀a฀ period฀(in฀this฀case,฀1920฀to฀2005). 7 ฀For฀any฀rating฀at฀the฀ beginning฀ of฀ the฀ year฀ (listed฀ in฀ the฀ left-hand฀ column฀ of฀ the฀table),฀the฀column฀of฀numbers฀running฀down฀from฀the฀ heading฀“Baa”฀tells฀us฀the฀probability฀that฀a฀company฀will฀ end฀up฀with฀a฀Baa฀rating฀at฀the฀end฀of฀the฀year. Again,฀ let’s฀ assume฀ management฀ wants฀ the฀ probabil- ity฀of฀its฀rating฀falling฀to฀Baa฀or฀lower฀over฀the฀next฀year฀ arising฀from฀natural฀catastrophes฀and฀equity฀markets. maximize฀ value฀ by฀ targeting฀ a฀ rating฀ of฀ A.฀ As฀ we฀ noted฀ Default the฀fiscal฀year฀falls฀below฀a฀default฀threshold฀level,฀which฀ is฀a฀function฀of฀the฀composition฀and฀amount฀of฀the฀firm’s฀ debt. 8 ฀Given฀this฀assumption,฀the฀firm฀needs฀the฀amount฀ of฀equity฀capital฀that฀will฀make฀the฀probability฀of฀its฀value฀ falling฀below฀the฀default฀threshold฀level฀equal฀to฀0.08%฀ Table 1 Transition Matrix from Moody’s Rating To: capital฀ is฀ straightforward.฀ To฀ see฀ this,฀ suppose฀ that฀ the฀ Rating From: Aaa Aa A Ba B Caa-C company฀ becomes฀ bankrupt฀ if฀ firm฀ value฀ at฀ the฀ end฀ of฀ from฀the฀probability฀of฀default฀to฀the฀required฀amount฀of฀ earlier,฀equity฀capital฀provides฀a฀buffer฀or฀shock฀absorber฀ Thus,฀to฀achieve฀an฀A฀rating,฀the฀company฀in฀our฀example฀ that฀ helps฀ the฀ firm฀ to฀ avoid฀ default.฀ For฀ a฀ given฀ firm,฀ a฀ different฀probability฀of฀default฀corresponds฀to฀each฀level฀of฀ equity,฀so฀that฀by฀choosing฀a฀given฀level฀of฀equity,฀manage- ment฀is฀also฀effectively฀choosing฀a฀probability฀of฀default฀that฀ it฀believes฀to฀be฀optimal. As฀can฀be฀seen฀in฀Table฀1,฀an฀A฀rating฀is฀associated฀with฀ a฀probability฀of฀default฀of฀0.08%฀over฀a฀one-year฀period.฀ must฀have฀the฀level฀of฀(equity)฀capital฀that฀makes฀its฀proba- just฀the฀amount฀of฀equity,฀the฀analytical฀process฀that฀leads฀ bility฀of฀default฀equal฀to฀0.08%.฀If฀we฀make฀the฀assumption฀ that฀ the฀ value฀ of฀ a฀ company’s฀ equity฀ falls฀ to฀ a฀ level฀ not฀ materially฀different฀from฀zero฀in฀the฀event฀of฀default,฀we฀ can฀use฀the฀probability฀of฀default฀to฀“back฀out”฀the฀amount฀ of฀equity฀the฀firm฀needs฀to฀support฀its฀current฀level฀of฀risk. Although฀the฀probability฀of฀default฀is฀in฀fact฀a฀compli- cated฀ function฀ of฀ a฀ number฀ of฀ firm฀ characteristics,฀ not฀ Baa Introduction Static Risk Appetite Numerical Dynamic Conclusion Parameter Values Assume the firm has a target credit rating of A, which leads to 0.08% default probability and around 6% financial distress probability 26 / 33

  66. ( ) ( ) α α α α α γ γ γ μ σ θ Baa 90.24% 5.67% 0.76% 0.12% 0.03% 0.08% 5.72% 0.05% 0.33% 5.05% 87.50% 0.08% 0.86% 0.18% 3.02% 0.75% A 0.00% 7.26% 0.79% 0.17% 0.02% 0.00% 0.00% Aa 0.06% 1.32% 90.71% 6.92% Ba 0.19% 0.04% 0.01% 0.31% 7.83% 0.01% 12 1.07% 7.69% 75.24% 15.69% Average one-year rating transition matrix, 1920-2005, conditional upon no rating withdrawal. Source: Moody’s Default and Recovery Rates of Corporate Bond Issuers, 1920-2005, March 2006. Journal of Applied Corporate Finance • Volume 18 Number 4 0.06% A Morgan Stanley Publication • Fall 2006 7. See footnote 2. 8. If all debt were due at the end of the year, the default threshold level would be the principal amount of debt outstanding plus interest due. However, if debt matures later, firm value could fall below the principal amount of debt outstanding without triggering a default. So, the default threshold level is lower than the principal amount of debt out- standing when the firm has long-term debt. 0.23% 0.03% 0.09% 0.00% 0.59% 6.70% 82.58% 0.72% 1.48% B 0.07% 0.00% 0.20% 0.80% 7.29% 80.62% 6.23% 4.78% Caa-C 91.75% Aaa Default In฀practice,฀however,฀the฀process฀of฀determining฀a฀target฀ to฀or฀lower฀than฀Baa฀along฀the฀row฀that฀corresponds฀to฀the฀ initial฀rating.฀The฀row฀where฀the฀probabilities฀of฀ending฀at฀ Baa฀or฀lower฀is฀closest฀to฀7%฀is฀the฀one฀corresponding฀to฀an฀ A฀rating.฀Consequently,฀by฀targeting฀an฀A฀rating,฀manage- ment฀would฀achieve฀the฀probability฀of฀financial฀distress฀that฀ is฀optimal฀for฀the฀firm.฀ rating฀ can฀ involve฀ more฀ considerations,฀ which฀ makes฀ it฀ downgrade฀to฀or฀lower฀than฀Baa฀for฀a฀given฀initial฀rating,฀ more฀complicated.฀For฀example,฀Nationwide฀analyzes฀and฀ manages฀both฀its฀probability฀of฀default฀and฀its฀probability฀of฀ downgrade,฀and฀it฀does฀so฀in฀separate฀but฀related฀frameworks.฀ The฀company’s฀optimal฀probability฀of฀default฀is฀anchored฀to฀ its฀target฀Aa฀ratings฀and฀reflects฀the฀default฀history฀of฀Aa- rated฀bonds.฀By฀contrast,฀the฀probability฀of฀downgrade฀to฀ Baa฀or฀below฀is฀assumed฀to฀be฀affected฀by,฀and฀is฀accord- we฀add฀up฀the฀probabilities฀of฀ending฀with฀a฀rating฀equal฀ to฀average฀around฀7%.฀To฀determine฀the฀probability฀of฀a฀ arising฀from฀natural฀catastrophes฀and฀equity฀markets. support฀a฀given฀level฀of฀risk.฀The฀transition฀matrix฀shown฀ of฀risk฀would฀be฀determined฀by฀comparing฀the฀costs฀associ- ated฀with฀financial฀distress฀and฀the฀benefits฀of฀having฀a฀more฀ levered฀capital฀structure฀and฀taking฀on฀riskier฀projects.฀ To฀the฀extent฀that฀ratings฀are฀reliable฀proxies฀for฀finan- cial฀health,฀companies฀can฀use฀a฀rating฀agency฀“transition฀ matrix”฀ to฀ estimate฀ the฀ amount฀ of฀ capital฀ necessary฀ to฀ in฀Table฀1฀can฀be฀used฀to฀identify฀the฀frequency฀with฀which฀ ity฀of฀its฀rating฀falling฀to฀Baa฀or฀lower฀over฀the฀next฀year฀ companies฀moved฀from฀one฀rating฀to฀another฀over฀a฀certain฀ period฀(in฀this฀case,฀1920฀to฀2005). 7 ฀For฀any฀rating฀at฀the฀ beginning฀ of฀ the฀ year฀ (listed฀ in฀ the฀ left-hand฀ column฀ of฀ the฀table),฀the฀column฀of฀numbers฀running฀down฀from฀the฀ heading฀“Baa”฀tells฀us฀the฀probability฀that฀a฀company฀will฀ end฀up฀with฀a฀Baa฀rating฀at฀the฀end฀of฀the฀year. Again,฀ let’s฀ assume฀ management฀ wants฀ the฀ probabil- ingly฀managed฀by฀limiting,฀risk฀concentrations฀such฀as฀those฀ In฀ the฀ example฀ above,฀ the฀ company฀ is฀ assumed฀ to฀ Caa-C Table 1 Transition Matrix from Moody’s company฀ becomes฀ bankrupt฀ if฀ firm฀ value฀ at฀ the฀ end฀ of฀ the฀fiscal฀year฀falls฀below฀a฀default฀threshold฀level,฀which฀ is฀a฀function฀of฀the฀composition฀and฀amount฀of฀the฀firm’s฀ debt. 8 ฀Given฀this฀assumption,฀the฀firm฀needs฀the฀amount฀ of฀equity฀capital฀that฀will฀make฀the฀probability฀of฀its฀value฀ falling฀below฀the฀default฀threshold฀level฀equal฀to฀0.08%฀ from฀the฀probability฀of฀default฀to฀the฀required฀amount฀of฀ Rating To: Rating From: Aaa Aa Baa Ba B capital฀ is฀ straightforward.฀ To฀ see฀ this,฀ suppose฀ that฀ the฀ just฀the฀amount฀of฀equity,฀the฀analytical฀process฀that฀leads฀ maximize฀ value฀ by฀ targeting฀ a฀ rating฀ of฀ A.฀ As฀ we฀ noted฀ a฀probability฀of฀default฀of฀0.08%฀over฀a฀one-year฀period.฀ earlier,฀equity฀capital฀provides฀a฀buffer฀or฀shock฀absorber฀ that฀ helps฀ the฀ firm฀ to฀ avoid฀ default.฀ For฀ a฀ given฀ firm,฀ a฀ different฀probability฀of฀default฀corresponds฀to฀each฀level฀of฀ equity,฀so฀that฀by฀choosing฀a฀given฀level฀of฀equity,฀manage- ment฀is฀also฀effectively฀choosing฀a฀probability฀of฀default฀that฀ it฀believes฀to฀be฀optimal. As฀can฀be฀seen฀in฀Table฀1,฀an฀A฀rating฀is฀associated฀with฀ Thus,฀to฀achieve฀an฀A฀rating,฀the฀company฀in฀our฀example฀ cated฀ function฀ of฀ a฀ number฀ of฀ firm฀ characteristics,฀ not฀ must฀have฀the฀level฀of฀(equity)฀capital฀that฀makes฀its฀proba- bility฀of฀default฀equal฀to฀0.08%.฀If฀we฀make฀the฀assumption฀ that฀ the฀ value฀ of฀ a฀ company’s฀ equity฀ falls฀ to฀ a฀ level฀ not฀ materially฀different฀from฀zero฀in฀the฀event฀of฀default,฀we฀ can฀use฀the฀probability฀of฀default฀to฀“back฀out”฀the฀amount฀ of฀equity฀the฀firm฀needs฀to฀support฀its฀current฀level฀of฀risk. Although฀the฀probability฀of฀default฀is฀in฀fact฀a฀compli- A Introduction Static Risk Appetite Numerical Dynamic Conclusion Parameter Values Assume the firm has a target credit rating of A, which leads to 0.08% default probability and around 6% financial distress probability Moody’s Transition Matrix 26 / 33

  67. 0.08% 0.01% 1.32% 90.71% 6.92% 0.75% 0.19% 0.04% 0.06% 0.00% A 0.08% 3.02% 90.24% 5.67% 0.76% Aa 0.00% 0.03% B Rating From: Aaa Aa A Baa Ba Caa-C 0.00% Default Aaa 91.75% 7.26% 0.79% 0.17% 0.02% 0.12% Source: Moody’s Default and Recovery Rates of Corporate Bond Issuers, 1920-2005, March 2006. 4.78% 0.07% 0.20% 0.80% 7.29% 80.62% 6.23% Caa-C B 0.00% 0.03% 0.06% 0.23% 1.07% 7.69% 75.24% 0.00% 1.48% Baa 0.18% 0.05% 0.33% 5.05% 87.50% 5.72% 0.86% 0.31% 0.72% Ba 0.01% 0.09% 0.59% 6.70% 82.58% 7.83% Rating To: Table 1 Transition Matrix from Moody’s Average one-year rating transition matrix, 1920-2005, conditional upon no rating withdrawal. to฀average฀around฀7%.฀To฀determine฀the฀probability฀of฀a฀ beginning฀ of฀ the฀ year฀ (listed฀ in฀ the฀ left-hand฀ column฀ of฀ the฀table),฀the฀column฀of฀numbers฀running฀down฀from฀the฀ heading฀“Baa”฀tells฀us฀the฀probability฀that฀a฀company฀will฀ end฀up฀with฀a฀Baa฀rating฀at฀the฀end฀of฀the฀year. Again,฀ let’s฀ assume฀ management฀ wants฀ the฀ probabil- ity฀of฀its฀rating฀falling฀to฀Baa฀or฀lower฀over฀the฀next฀year฀ downgrade฀to฀or฀lower฀than฀Baa฀for฀a฀given฀initial฀rating,฀ companies฀moved฀from฀one฀rating฀to฀another฀over฀a฀certain฀ we฀add฀up฀the฀probabilities฀of฀ending฀with฀a฀rating฀equal฀ to฀or฀lower฀than฀Baa฀along฀the฀row฀that฀corresponds฀to฀the฀ initial฀rating.฀The฀row฀where฀the฀probabilities฀of฀ending฀at฀ Baa฀or฀lower฀is฀closest฀to฀7%฀is฀the฀one฀corresponding฀to฀an฀ A฀rating.฀Consequently,฀by฀targeting฀an฀A฀rating,฀manage- ment฀would฀achieve฀the฀probability฀of฀financial฀distress฀that฀ is฀optimal฀for฀the฀firm.฀ period฀(in฀this฀case,฀1920฀to฀2005). 7 ฀For฀any฀rating฀at฀the฀ in฀Table฀1฀can฀be฀used฀to฀identify฀the฀frequency฀with฀which฀ rating฀ can฀ involve฀ more฀ considerations,฀ which฀ makes฀ it฀ A Morgan Stanley Publication • Fall 2006 standing when the firm has long-term debt. default. So, the default threshold level is lower than the principal amount of debt out- firm value could fall below the principal amount of debt outstanding without triggering a principal amount of debt outstanding plus interest due. However, if debt matures later, 8. If all debt were due at the end of the year, the default threshold level would be the 7. See footnote 2. Journal of Applied Corporate Finance • Volume 18 Number 4 support฀a฀given฀level฀of฀risk.฀The฀transition฀matrix฀shown฀ 12 of฀risk฀would฀be฀determined฀by฀comparing฀the฀costs฀associ- ated฀with฀financial฀distress฀and฀the฀benefits฀of฀having฀a฀more฀ levered฀capital฀structure฀and฀taking฀on฀riskier฀projects.฀ To฀the฀extent฀that฀ratings฀are฀reliable฀proxies฀for฀finan- cial฀health,฀companies฀can฀use฀a฀rating฀agency฀“transition฀ matrix”฀ to฀ estimate฀ the฀ amount฀ of฀ capital฀ necessary฀ to฀ In฀practice,฀however,฀the฀process฀of฀determining฀a฀target฀ more฀complicated.฀For฀example,฀Nationwide฀analyzes฀and฀ falling฀below฀the฀default฀threshold฀level฀equal฀to฀0.08%฀ cated฀ function฀ of฀ a฀ number฀ of฀ firm฀ characteristics,฀ not฀ bility฀of฀default฀equal฀to฀0.08%.฀If฀we฀make฀the฀assumption฀ that฀ the฀ value฀ of฀ a฀ company’s฀ equity฀ falls฀ to฀ a฀ level฀ not฀ materially฀different฀from฀zero฀in฀the฀event฀of฀default,฀we฀ can฀use฀the฀probability฀of฀default฀to฀“back฀out”฀the฀amount฀ of฀equity฀the฀firm฀needs฀to฀support฀its฀current฀level฀of฀risk. Although฀the฀probability฀of฀default฀is฀in฀fact฀a฀compli- just฀the฀amount฀of฀equity,฀the฀analytical฀process฀that฀leads฀ Thus,฀to฀achieve฀an฀A฀rating,฀the฀company฀in฀our฀example฀ from฀the฀probability฀of฀default฀to฀the฀required฀amount฀of฀ capital฀ is฀ straightforward.฀ To฀ see฀ this,฀ suppose฀ that฀ the฀ company฀ becomes฀ bankrupt฀ if฀ firm฀ value฀ at฀ the฀ end฀ of฀ the฀fiscal฀year฀falls฀below฀a฀default฀threshold฀level,฀which฀ is฀a฀function฀of฀the฀composition฀and฀amount฀of฀the฀firm’s฀ debt. 8 ฀Given฀this฀assumption,฀the฀firm฀needs฀the฀amount฀ of฀equity฀capital฀that฀will฀make฀the฀probability฀of฀its฀value฀ must฀have฀the฀level฀of฀(equity)฀capital฀that฀makes฀its฀proba- a฀probability฀of฀default฀of฀0.08%฀over฀a฀one-year฀period.฀ manages฀both฀its฀probability฀of฀default฀and฀its฀probability฀of฀ arising฀from฀natural฀catastrophes฀and฀equity฀markets. downgrade,฀and฀it฀does฀so฀in฀separate฀but฀related฀frameworks.฀ The฀company’s฀optimal฀probability฀of฀default฀is฀anchored฀to฀ its฀target฀Aa฀ratings฀and฀reflects฀the฀default฀history฀of฀Aa- rated฀bonds.฀By฀contrast,฀the฀probability฀of฀downgrade฀to฀ Baa฀or฀below฀is฀assumed฀to฀be฀affected฀by,฀and฀is฀accord- ingly฀managed฀by฀limiting,฀risk฀concentrations฀such฀as฀those฀ In฀ the฀ example฀ above,฀ the฀ company฀ is฀ assumed฀ to฀ As฀can฀be฀seen฀in฀Table฀1,฀an฀A฀rating฀is฀associated฀with฀ maximize฀ value฀ by฀ targeting฀ a฀ rating฀ of฀ A.฀ As฀ we฀ noted฀ earlier,฀equity฀capital฀provides฀a฀buffer฀or฀shock฀absorber฀ that฀ helps฀ the฀ firm฀ to฀ avoid฀ default.฀ For฀ a฀ given฀ firm,฀ a฀ different฀probability฀of฀default฀corresponds฀to฀each฀level฀of฀ equity,฀so฀that฀by฀choosing฀a฀given฀level฀of฀equity,฀manage- ment฀is฀also฀effectively฀choosing฀a฀probability฀of฀default฀that฀ it฀believes฀to฀be฀optimal. 15.69% Introduction Static Risk Appetite Numerical Dynamic Conclusion Parameter Values Assume the firm has a target credit rating of A, which leads to 0.08% default probability and around 6% financial distress probability Moody’s Transition Matrix Parameter Value Risk Appetite Risk Limits ( ) ( ) α α α α P A α r r l op m 1 2 3 4 0 0 0.05 0.05 0.05 0.05 0.0008 0 0 0.2 0.01 Hazard Risk Op Risk Factors Strategic Factor Borrowed Capital γ γ γ μ σ θ d c 1 2 3 0.01 0.1 0.1 0.2 0.2 0.1 0.5 0.7 26 / 33

  68. Introduction Static Risk Appetite Numerical Dynamic Conclusion Optimization Results Optimization Results under the Baseline Setting Decision Variable Optimal Value Investment in the R&D project 0.0558 Investment in the manufacturing project 0.6228 Investment in the index fund 0.0542 Investment in the Treasury bill 0.2546 The proportion of hazard risk insured 0.9479 Optimal Return 1.0806 27 / 33

  69. Introduction Static Risk Appetite Numerical Dynamic Conclusion Risk Prioritization No Prioritization vs. With Prioritization No Prioritization With Prioritization All α ’s = 0.05 α 1 = 0.1, α 4 = 0.01 Decision Variable Investment in the R&D project 0.0558 0.0991 Investment in the manufacturing project 0.6228 0.5197 Investment in the index fund 0.0542 0.0647 Investment in the Treasury bill 0.2546 0.3039 The proportion of hazard risk insured 0.9479 0.9625 Optimal Return 1.0806 1.0862 28 / 33

  70. Introduction Static Risk Appetite Numerical Dynamic Conclusion Interactions Between Risks High Op Risk Factors vs. Low Op Risk Factors High Op Factors Low Op Factors Decision Variable ( γ 1 =0.2, γ 2 =0.1) ( γ 1 =0.05, γ 2 =0.05) R&D project 0.0558 0.0813 Manufacturing project 0.6228 0.9062 Index fund 0.0542 0 Treasury bill 0.2546 0 Hazard risk insured 0.9479 0.9479 Optimal Return 1.0806 1.1004 29 / 33

  71. Introduction Static Risk Appetite Numerical Dynamic Conclusion Two-Period Setting Risk/return optimization in a two-period planning horizon Three broad types of investment opportunities Short-term (one-period) real projects: invest at the beginning of each period, return at end of each period Long-term (two-period) real projects: invest at the beginning of period 1, return at end of period 2 Financial assets 30 / 33

  72. Introduction Static Risk Appetite Numerical Dynamic Conclusion Strategic Time Line r P2 = E[ R P2 | I0 ] (1) = E[ R j (1) | I0 ], (2) = E[ R j (2) | I0 ], r j r j E[ C (1) ] j = P 1 or A j = P 1 or A C (0) Time 0 Time 1 Time 2 31 / 33

  73. Introduction Static Risk Appetite Numerical Dynamic Conclusion Strategic Time Line r P2 = E[ R P2 | I0 ] (1) = E[ R j (1) | I0 ], (2) = E[ R j (2) | I0 ], r j r j E[ C (1) ] j = P 1 or A j = P 1 or A C (0) Time 0 Time 1 Time 2 ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) , u (1) , u (2) 1 1 2 2 w , w 2 , w w , w P 1 j P l Ak P 1 j Ak 1 1 2 2 31 / 33

Download Presentation
Download Policy: The content available on the website is offered to you 'AS IS' for your personal information and use only. It cannot be commercialized, licensed, or distributed on other websites without prior consent from the author. To download a presentation, simply click this link. If you encounter any difficulties during the download process, it's possible that the publisher has removed the file from their server.

Recommend


More recommend