endogenous growth through r d empirical issues and
play

Endogenous growth through R&D Empirical issues and extensions - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

Endogenous growth through R&D Empirical issues and extensions Carl-Johan Dalgaard Lecture notes May 2 00 7 A SIMPLE VERSION OF THE R&D MODEL Consider the model from B&S Ch. 6 with a slight simpli fi cation to fascilitate the


  1. Endogenous growth through R&D — Empirical issues and extensions Carl-Johan Dalgaard Lecture notes May 2 00 7

  2. A SIMPLE VERSION OF THE R&D MODEL Consider the model from B&S Ch. 6 with a slight simpli fi cation to fascilitate the discussion. That is, we have the following structure. First, equilibrium production of each variety: 2 1 x = α ¯ 1 − α A 1 − α L, Second, total output is, in symmetrical equilibrium: 1 2 α x α L 1 − α N = A Y = A ¯ 1 − α α 1 − α NL Third, we have the resource constaint of the economy x + η ˙ Y = C + N ¯ N, 2

  3. A SIMPLE VERSION OF THE R&D MODEL so new ideas are produced assuming a lab-equipment formulation N = Y R η ≡ s R ˙ η Y, where s R is endogenous. Finally, here is the simpli fi cation: C = (1 − s ) Y, i.e. in stead of Ramsey-consumers, we have "Solowian" consumption behavior. Inserting the consumption function into the resource con- staint, and rearrangeing, gives us h i s − N ¯ x Y x + η ˙ N ⇔ ˙ Y = (1 − s ) Y + N ¯ N = Y η 3

  4. A SIMPLE VERSION OF THE R&D MODEL Finally, inserting for ¯ x and Y leaves us with " # Y ≡ s ∗ s − α 2 ˙ R N = η Y. η Hence, in this version of the model the growth rate of the economy is simply µ Y ¶ ∗ 1 2 α N = s ∗ ˙ N A 1 − α α 1 − α L = s ∗ R R η N η where obviously g N = g Y , and due to C = (1 − s ) Y , it clearly follows that g C = g N = g Y . That is, balanced growth prevails. We are therefore left with a couple of testable predictions. (1) All other things remaining equal, a higher investment share in R&D should lead to faster growth. (2) A larger labor force should lead to faster growth. 4

  5. INVESTMENTS IN R&D AND PROSPERITY Given the lab-equipment R&D model we essentially have developed some microfoundations for an assumption like ˙ N = s R Y. That is, new ideas — or technology — are the result of investments in R&D. Nonneman and Vanhoudt (1996) use this formulation to provide a (further) augmentation of the Solow model, thus taking the empirical work of Mankiw, Romer and Weil (1992) slightly further. In their model s R is exogenous. Q: is higher s R associated with faster growth? Also another motiva- tion for re-visiting MR W: The human capital augmented solow model does not seem to do a particularly good job in explaining productivity di ff erences in the OECD. 5

  6. INVESTMENTS IN R&D AND PROSPERITY Figure 1: MRW p. 426. The growth regression neither physical capital nor human capital are signi fi cant at 5%. In Levels-regressions, the fi t becomes progressivly poorer as the sample is limited. 6

  7. INVESTMENTS IN R&D AND PROSPERITY Nonneman and Vanhoudt simply adds “knowledge capital" to the list of inputs Y = K α H β N γ ( AL ) 1 − α − γ − β . “A" is an exognous source of technological progress. Stricktly speaking, therefore, the model suggests that changes in s R (for example) only leads to level e ff ects. Growth e ff ects are interpreted as transitional dynamics. A property of the steady state is worth fl eshing out. Since ˙ N Y N = s R N, and assuming exogenous growth of x percent, labor force growth of n ³ ´ ∗ ³ ´ ∗ Y Y = n + x percent implies that, in steady state, n + x = s R ⇔ s R . N N Under competitive markets, the “Return to R&D" is γ Y N . Hence R = γn + x r ∗ . s R 7

  8. INVESTMENTS IN R&D AND PROSPERITY Figure 2: Nonneman and Vanhoudt (1996), p. 950 * s R does seem to be associated with faster growth (under the model — in transition to steady state). * In general the augmentation improves the fi t. α is estimated to about 1 / 3 . 8

  9. INVESTMENTS IN R&D AND PROSPERITY * Compared with MR W the impact from HC is lowered ( β ≈ . 15 ) * Also, they fi nd γ ≈ . 085 . Plausible? Taking this fi nding seriously allows for a consistency check. Consider the US: n = . 025 , x = 0 . 02 and s R = 0 . 025 gives r ∗ R = . 085 . 045 0 . 025 ≈ 0 . 153 (or about .20 if we also added a depreciation rate). Is this plausible? * There is a literature which attempts to estimate r R directly , using industry data. An idea that goes back to Grilliches (1979, Bell Journal of Economics). To illustrate. First step, di ff . the production tech wrt time g Y = αg K + βg H + γg N + (1 − α − β − γ ) ( x + n ) . 9

  10. INVESTMENTS IN R&D AND PROSPERITY Now suppose indeed ˙ N/N = g N = s R Y/N. Substitute back into the above equation g Y = αg K + βg H + γs R Y/N + (1 − α − β − γ ) ( x + n ) Since, in theory, γ = r R N/Y we now have g Y = αg K + βg H + r R s R + (1 − α − β − γ ) ( x + n ) , where s R are R&D investments in value added. We can think of r R as a paramter to be estimated (not without problems). Grilliches fi nd r R , for the US, to be around 20%; which is roughly consistent with Nonneman and Vanhoudts fi ndings. 10

  11. INVESTMENTS IN R&D, SCALE AND PROSPERITY Going back to our expression for the growth rate: µ Y ¶ ∗ 1 2 α N = s ∗ ˙ N A 1 − α α 1 − α L = s ∗ R g Y = R η N η N&V provide some evidence in favor of the prediction that s ∗ R ↑ goes along with γ Y ↑ ; at least in the OECD (and at least in transition). But the model also suggest that L ↑ should lead to accelerating growth. In more “general R&D models", this would be "R&D labor", not just the labor force. Still, eventually the two would be proportional. This implication is heavily criticized by Jones (1995), and started the "scale controversy". 11

  12. INVESTMENTS IN R&D, SCALE AND PROSPERITY Figure 3: Jones, 1995; p. 517. Basic point: R&D labor has increased, but g Y is US (and other places) have remained stationary. So can we come up with an alternative model? 12

  13. A “SEMI-ENDOGENOUS" GROWTH MODEL We keep basically the entire Romer framework, leading to : 1 2 α A 1 − α α 1 − α L g Y = g N = s ∗ . R η But, assume now that η ( N ) = φN σ , φ > 0 , σ > 0 . That is, suppose it progressively becomes more and more di ffi cult to shift the frontier (to innovate), and therefore more costly to get the next good idea. 1 . We now have 1 2 α A 1 − α α 1 − α L g N = s ∗ . R φN σ 1 A version with Ramsey savings is discussed in B&S ch. 6.1.8. 13

  14. A “SEMI-ENDOGENOUS" GROWTH MODEL Is constant per capita growth feasible? Yes if L increases. Di ff . the growth rate wrt time g N ˙ = n − σg N = 0 , g N which therefore requires N = 1 g ∗ σn > n for σ < 1 . Key implications : 1. Per capita growth rate is µ 1 − σ ¶ g ∗ Y − n = g ∗ N − n = n. σ Hence constant growth in labor force (science input) is associated with constant growth in GDP per capita. n is exogenous, but tech. change endogenous (“semi") 14

  15. A “SEMI-ENDOGENOUS" GROWTH MODEL 2. Policies (which matter for e.g. s R ) does not matter for the growth rate; but for the level of income per capita. To see this, note that on a balanced growth path µ L ¶ ∗ 1 2 α σn = s ∗ R A 1 − α α N = 1 1 − α g ∗ N σ φ so the level of N   1 /σ 1 2 α  s ∗ R A 1 − α α 1 − α N ∗ =  L 1 /σ . φ 1 σ n so   1 /σ µ Y ¶ ∗ 1 2 α  s ∗ R A 1 − α α 1 − α 1 2 α 1 2 α 1 − α N ∗ = A L (0) 1 /σ e ( n/σ ) t .  = A 1 − α α 1 − α α 1 − α φ 1 L σ n 15

  16. A “SEMI-ENDOGENOUS" GROWTH MODEL 3. Scale still matters, but in a more subtle way: more L implies a higher level of GDP per worker. 4. worrisome prediction: If n declines (or fall), eventually growth in GDP per worker should move in the same direction, since g ∗ y = ³ ´ 1 − σ n. σ As a matter of transitional dynamics: If n falls the growth rate in N (thus Y/L ) should be either montonically declining, or follow a hump shaped path (Phase diagram). 16

  17. CONTRASTING EVIDENCE: HA AND HOWITT (2005) Figure 4: Ha and Howitt, 2005; p. 11 Observation 1: From 1950-2000 TFP growth has remained stationary. 17

  18. CONTRASTING EVIDENCE: HA AND HOWITT (2005) Figure 5: Ha and Howitt, 2005, p. 14 Observation 2: Growth in R&D input (however measured) has not remained constant. 18

  19. CONTRASTING EVIDENCE: HA AND HOWITT (2005) Figure 6: H & H (2005), p. 17 Observation 3: The share of R&D in GDP (i.e. s ∗ R ) has remained constant. Obs. 1 -3 hard to reconsile with semi-endogenous growth theory 19

  20. A SIMPLE MODEL WHICH IS CONSISTENT WITH THE EVIDENCE (Dalgaard and Kreiner, 2001) Final output, Y t , is produced using human capital augmented labor in- put, H t = h t L t , ideas, N t , and some fi xed factor of production denoted by Z t Z 1 − α N β Y t = H α t , Z ≡ 1 , 0 < α < 1 , 0 < β ≤ 1 Ideas are produced using units of fi nal output (the ’lab-equipment’ framework): ˙ N t = s R Y t , N 0 given The parameter s R denotes the share of total output invested in R&D. 20

  21. A SIMPLE MODEL WHICH IS CONSISTENT WITH THE EVIDENCE Assume: ( a ) H t = h t L t , ˙ L t /L t = n , and h t endogenously growing. ( b ) β < 1 and α + β = 1 . Does perpetual human capital accumulation make sense? - Human capital is not just quantity of information but also quality - Complementarity between human capital and scienti fi c knowledge ⇒ If science continues to progress, i.e. ˙ N/N > 0 , quality of knowledge may continue to expand. 21

Download Presentation
Download Policy: The content available on the website is offered to you 'AS IS' for your personal information and use only. It cannot be commercialized, licensed, or distributed on other websites without prior consent from the author. To download a presentation, simply click this link. If you encounter any difficulties during the download process, it's possible that the publisher has removed the file from their server.

Recommend


More recommend