dummy endogenous variables in a
play

Dummy Endogenous Variables in a Simultaneous Equation System - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

Dummy Endogenous Variables in a Simultaneous Equation System Econometrica, Vol. 46, No. 4 (Jul., 1978), 931-959. James J. Heckman Econ 312, Spring 2019 Heckman 5/29/2019 1. A GENERAL MODEL FOR THE TWO EQUATION CASE Heckman Dummy Endogenous


  1. Dummy Endogenous Variables in a Simultaneous Equation System Econometrica, Vol. 46, No. 4 (Jul., 1978), 931-959. James J. Heckman Econ 312, Spring 2019 Heckman 5/29/2019

  2. 1. A GENERAL MODEL FOR THE TWO EQUATION CASE Heckman Dummy Endogenous Variables

  3. ∗ and y 2i ∗ , • Pair of simultaneous equations for continuous latent random variables 𝑧 1𝑗 ∗ = 𝑌 1𝑗 𝛽 1 + 𝑒 𝑗 𝛾 1 + 𝑧 2𝑗 ∗ 𝜇 1 + 𝑉 1𝑗 , (1a) 𝑧 1𝑗 ∗ = 𝑌 2𝑗 𝛽 2 + 𝑒 𝑗 𝛾 2 + 𝑧 1𝑗 ∗ 𝜇 2 + 𝑉 2𝑗 , (2a) 𝑧 2𝑗 where dummy variable 𝑒 𝑗 is defined by ∗ > 0 , (1c) 𝑒 𝑗 = 1 iff 𝑧 2𝑗 𝑒 𝑗 = 0 otherwise, and 2 = 𝜏 𝐹 𝑉 𝑘𝑗 = 0, 𝐹 𝑉 𝑘𝑘 , 𝐹 𝑉 1𝑗 𝑉 2𝑗 = 𝜏 12 , 𝑘 = 1,2; 𝑗 = 1, … , 𝐽. 𝑘𝑗 𝑘𝑗 𝑉 𝑘 ′ 𝑗 ′ = 0, for 𝑘, 𝑘 ′ = 1,2; 𝑗 ≠ 𝑗 ′ . 𝐹 𝑉 “ 𝑌 1𝑗 ” and “ 𝑌 2𝑗 ” are, respectively, 1 × 𝐿 1 and 1 × 𝐿 2 row vectors of bounded exogenous variables. Heckman Dummy Endogenous Variables

  4. • Equations (1a) and (1b) are identified under standard conditions if 𝛾 1 = 𝛾 2 = ∗ and 𝑧 2𝑗 ∗ are observed for each of the I observations. 0 and both 𝑧 1𝑗 • In this special case, which conforms to the classical simultaneous equation model, standard methods are available to estimate all of the parameters of the structure. ∗ and 𝑧 2𝑗 ∗ which • First, note that the model is cast in terms of latent variables 𝑧 1𝑗 may or may not be directly observed. ∗ is never observed, the event 𝑧 2𝑗 ∗ > 0 is observed and its occurrence • Even if 𝑧 2𝑗 is recorded by setting a dummy variable, 𝑒 𝑗 equal to one. ∗ < 0, the dummy variable assumes the value zero. • If 𝑧 2𝑗 ∗ > 0, structural equations (1a) and (1b) are shifted by an • Second, note that if 𝑧 2𝑗 amount 𝛾 1 and 𝛾 2 , respectively. Heckman Dummy Endogenous Variables

  5. • To fix ideas, several plausible economic models are discussed that may be described by equation system (1a)-(1c). ∗ and 𝑧 2𝑗 ∗ are observed outcomes of a market at • First, suppose that both 𝑧 1𝑗 time i, say quantity and price. • Equation (1a) is the demand curve while equation (1b) is the supply curve. • If the price exceeds some threshold (zero in inequality (1c), but this can be readily amended t be any positive constant), the government takes certain actions that shift both the supply curve and the demand curve, say a subsidy to consumers and a per unit subsidy to producers. • These actions shift the demand curve and the supply curve by the amount 𝛾 1 and 𝛾 2 , respectively. Heckman Dummy Endogenous Variables

  6. • As another example, consider a model of the effect of laws on the status of blacks. ∗ be the measured income of blacks in state i while 𝑧 2𝑗 ∗ is an • Let 𝑧 1𝑗 unmeasured variable that reflects the state’s population sentiment toward blacks. ∗ > 0 the state may • If sentiment for blacks is sufficiently favorable 𝑧 2𝑗 enact antidiscrimination legislation and the presence of such legislation in state i , a variable that can be measured, is denoted by a dummy variable 𝑒 𝑗 = 1 . • In the income equation (1a), both the presence of a law and the population sentiment towards blacks is assumed to affect the measured income of blacks. • The first effect is assumed to operate discretely while the second effect is assumed to operate in a more continuous fashion. Heckman Dummy Endogenous Variables

  7. • Two conceptually distinct roles for dummy variables: 1. As indicators of latent variables that cross thresholds and 2. As direct shifters of behavioral functions. These two roles must be carefully distinguished. Heckman Dummy Endogenous Variables

  8. • The model of equations (1a)-(1c) subsumes a wide variety of interesting econometric models. These special cases are briefly discussed in turn. • CASE l: The Classical Simultaneous Equation Model: This model ∗ and 𝑧 2𝑗 ∗ are observed, and there is no structural shift arises when 𝑧 1𝑗 in the equations (𝛾 1 = 𝛾 2 = 0) . • CASE 2: The Classical Simultaneous Equation Model with Structural Shift: This model is the same as that of Case 1 except that structural shift is permitted in each equation. It will be shown below that certain restrictions must be imposed on the model in order to generate a sensible statistical structure for this case. Heckman Dummy Endogenous Variables

  9. • CASE 3: The Multivariate Probit Model: This model arises when ∗ and 𝑧 2𝑗 ∗ are not observed but the events 𝑧 1𝑗 ∗ and 𝑧 2𝑗 ∗ are observed 𝑧 1𝑗 (i.e., one knows whether or not the latent variables have crossed a threshold). The notation of equations (1a)-(1b) must be altered to accommodate two dummy variables but that modification is obvious. No structural shift is permitted ( 𝛾 1 = 𝛾 2 = 0 ). This is the model of Ashford and Sowden [3], Amemiya [2], and Zellner and Lee [30]. • CASE 4: The Multivariate Probit Model with Structural Shift: This model is the same as that of Case 3 except that structural shift is permitted ( 𝛾 1 = 𝛾 2 = 0 ). Heckman Dummy Endogenous Variables

  10. ∗ is • CASE 5: The Hybrid Model: This model arises when 𝑧 1𝑗 ∗ ≷ 0 is observed. No ∗ is not, but the event 𝑧 2𝑗 observed and 𝑧 2𝑗 structural shift is permitted ( 𝛾 1 = 𝛾 2 = 0 ). • CASE 6: The Hybrid Model with Structural Shift: This model is the same as that of Case 5 except that structural shifts in the equations are permitted. Heckman Dummy Endogenous Variables

  11. 2. THE HYBRID MODEL WITH STRUCTURAL SHIFT Heckman Dummy Endogenous Variables

  12. • In this section, a model with one observed continuous random variable, and one latent random variable is analyzed for the general case of structural shift in the equations. • Consider identification only; Heckman (1978) for additional discussion. Heckman Dummy Endogenous Variables

  13. • To facilitate the discussion, equations (1a) and (1b) may be written in semi-reduced form as Heckman Dummy Endogenous Variables

  14. • In the ensuing analysis it is assumed that exogenous variables included in both 𝑌 1𝑗 and 𝑌 2𝑗 are allocated to either 𝑌 1𝑗 or 𝑌 2𝑗 but not both. • The absence of an asterisk on 𝑧 1𝑗 denotes that this variable is observed. ∗ ” is not observed. • “ 𝑧 2𝑗 • Random variables 𝑉 1𝑗 and 𝑉 2𝑗 are assumed to be bivariate normal random variables. • Accordingly, the joint distribution of 𝑊 1𝑗 , 𝑊 2𝑗 , ℎ(𝑊 1𝑗 , 𝑊 2𝑗 ) , is a bivariate normal density fully characterized by the following assumptions: 𝐹 𝑊 1𝑗 = 0, 𝐹 𝑊 2𝑗 = 0, 2 2 𝐹 𝑊 = 𝜕 1𝑗 , 𝐹 𝑊 1𝑗 𝑊 2𝑗 = 𝜕 12 , 𝐹 𝑊 = 𝜕 22 . 1𝑗 2𝑗 Heckman Dummy Endogenous Variables

  15. Heckman Dummy Endogenous Variables

  16. (i) Conditions for Existence of the Model Heckman Dummy Endogenous Variables

  17. • The first order of business is to determine whether or not the model of equations (1a)-(1b) as represented in reduced form by equations (3a)-(3b) makes sense. • Without imposing a further restriction, it does not. • The restriction required is precisely the restriction implicitly assumed in writing equations (3a) and (3b), i.e., the restriction that permits one to define a unique probability statement for the events 𝑒 𝑗 = 1 and 𝑒 𝑗 = 0 so that 𝑄 𝑗 in fact exists. • A necessary and sufficient condition for this to be so is that 𝜌 23 = 0 , i.e., that the probability of the event 𝑒 𝑗 = 1 is not a determinant of the event. • Equivalently, this assumption can be written as the requirement that 𝛿 2 𝛾 1 + 𝛾 2 = 0 . • This condition is critical to the analysis and thus deserves some discussion. • The argument supporting this assumption is summarized in the following proposition. Heckman Dummy Endogenous Variables

  18. PROPOSITION: A necessary and sufficient condition for the model of equations (1a)-(1c) or (3a)-(3c) to be defined is that 𝜌 23 = 0 = 𝛿 2 𝛾 1 + 𝛾 2 . This assumption is termed the principal assumption. PROOF: Sufficiency is obvious. Thus, only necessary conditions are discussed. Denote the joint density of 𝑊 2𝑗 , 𝑒 𝑗 by 𝑢(𝑊 2𝑗 , 𝑒 𝑗 ) which is assumed to be a proper density in the sense that ∞ 𝑢(𝑊 2𝑗 , 𝑒 𝑗 ) 𝑒𝑊 2𝑗 = 1. −∞ 𝑒 𝑗 =0,1 ∗ ⩾ 0 given 𝑒 𝑗 = 1 must be • From equations (3b) and (3c), the probability that 𝑧 2𝑗 unity, so that one may write Pr 𝑊 2𝑗 > 𝑚 𝑗 𝑒 𝑗 = 1 = 1 ′ = ′ are defined by 𝑚 𝑗 = − 𝑌 1𝑗 𝜌 21 + 𝑌 22 + 𝜌 23 and 𝑚 𝑗 where the symbols 𝑚 𝑗 and 𝑚 𝑗 𝑚 𝑗 + 𝜌 23 . Heckman Dummy Endogenous Variables

  19. • Alternatively, one may write this condition as ∞ 𝑢(𝑊 2𝑗 , 1) 𝑒𝑊 2𝑗 = 𝑄 𝑗 (4a) 𝑚 𝑗 and obviously 𝑚 𝑗 𝑢 𝑊 2𝑗 , 1 𝑒𝑊 2𝑗 = 0. (4b) −∞ • Using similar reasoning, one can conclude that ′ 𝑚 𝑗 𝑢 𝑊 2𝑗 , 1 𝑒𝑊 2𝑗 = 1 − 𝑄 𝑗 (4c) −∞ and ∞ 𝑢 𝑊 2𝑗 , 0 𝑒𝑊 2𝑗 = 0. (4d) ′ 𝑚 𝑗 Heckman Dummy Endogenous Variables

Download Presentation
Download Policy: The content available on the website is offered to you 'AS IS' for your personal information and use only. It cannot be commercialized, licensed, or distributed on other websites without prior consent from the author. To download a presentation, simply click this link. If you encounter any difficulties during the download process, it's possible that the publisher has removed the file from their server.

Recommend


More recommend