duality and derivative pricing with time changed l vy
play

Duality and Derivative Pricing with Time-Changed Lvy Processes Jos - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

Duality and Derivative Pricing with Time-Changed Lvy Processes Jos e Fajardo Ernesto Mordecki IBMEC Business School Universidad de La Republica del Uruguay Fourth Bachelier Finance Society Congress. Tokyo, August 20, 2006 p. 1/3


  1. Duality and Derivative Pricing with Time-Changed Lévy Processes Jos´ e Fajardo Ernesto Mordecki IBMEC Business School Universidad de La Republica del Uruguay Fourth Bachelier Finance Society Congress. Tokyo, August 20, 2006 – p. 1/3

  2. Outline • Motivation – p. 2/3

  3. Outline • Motivation • Time-Changed Lévy processes – p. 2/3

  4. Outline • Motivation • Time-Changed Lévy processes • Bidimensional Derivative pricing – p. 2/3

  5. Outline • Motivation • Time-Changed Lévy processes • Bidimensional Derivative pricing • Duality and Symmetry – p. 2/3

  6. Outline • Motivation • Time-Changed Lévy processes • Bidimensional Derivative pricing • Duality and Symmetry • Conclusions – p. 2/3

  7. Motivation BiDimensional Derivative Pricing: European type American Perpetual type BM Margrabe (1978) Gerber and Shiu (1996) LP Fajardo and Mordecki (2006) Fajardo and Mordecki (2006) AP Eberlein and Papantaleon (2005b) ? TCLP This Paper ? – p. 3/3

  8. Motivation BiDimensional Derivative Pricing: European type American Perpetual type BM Margrabe (1978) Gerber and Shiu (1996) LP Fajardo and Mordecki (2006) Fajardo and Mordecki (2006) AP Eberlein and Papantaleon (2005b) ? TCLP This Paper ? Duality Put-Call Exotic Derivatives BM Carr and Chesney (1996) Henderson and Wojakowski (2002) LP Fajardo and Mordecki (2006) Eberlein and Papantaleon (2005a) AP Eberlein and Papantaleon (2005b) ? TCLP This Paper ? SM Schroder (1999) ? – p. 3/3

  9. Lévy Processes We say that X = { X t } t ≥ 0 is a Lévy Process, or a process with stationary and independent increments, if: – p. 4/3

  10. Lévy Processes We say that X = { X t } t ≥ 0 is a Lévy Process, or a process with stationary and independent increments, if: • X has paths RCLL – p. 4/3

  11. Lévy Processes We say that X = { X t } t ≥ 0 is a Lévy Process, or a process with stationary and independent increments, if: • X has paths RCLL • X 0 = 0 , and has independent increments, given 0 < t 1 < t 2 < ... < t n , the r.v. X t 1 , X t 2 − X t 1 , · · · , X t n − X t n − 1 are independents. – p. 4/3

  12. Lévy Processes We say that X = { X t } t ≥ 0 is a Lévy Process, or a process with stationary and independent increments, if: • X has paths RCLL • X 0 = 0 , and has independent increments, given 0 < t 1 < t 2 < ... < t n , the r.v. X t 1 , X t 2 − X t 1 , · · · , X t n − X t n − 1 are independents. • The distribution of the increment X t − X s is homogenous in time, that is, depends just on the difference t − s . – p. 4/3

  13. Lévy-Khintchine Formula A key result in the theory of Lévy Processes is the Lévy-Khintchine formula, that computes de characteristic function of X t as: E ( e zX t ) = e tψ ( z ) – p. 5/3

  14. Lévy-Khintchine Formula A key result in the theory of Lévy Processes is the Lévy-Khintchine formula, that computes de characteristic function of X t as: E ( e zX t ) = e tψ ( z ) Where ψ is called characteristic exponent , and is given by: – p. 5/3

  15. Lévy-Khintchine Formula A key result in the theory of Lévy Processes is the Lévy-Khintchine formula, that computes de characteristic function of X t as: E ( e zX t ) = e tψ ( z ) Where ψ is called characteristic exponent , and is given by: � ψ ( z ) = bz + 1 2 σ 2 z 2 + ( e zy − 1 − zy 1 {| y | < 1 } ) Π ( dy ) , I R where b and σ ≥ 0 are real constants, and Π is a positive measure in I R − { 0 } such that � (1 ∧ y 2 )Π( dy ) < ∞ , and is called Lévy measure, – p. 5/3

  16. Remarks • Due to the independence of increments we can not model range dependence. – p. 6/3

  17. Remarks • Due to the independence of increments we can not model range dependence. • Due to the homogeneity in time we can not have flexible representations for the term structure of volatility. – p. 6/3

  18. This Paper • Time-inhomogenous Processes – p. 7/3

  19. This Paper • Time-inhomogenous Processes • Derivative Pricing and Duality Relationship. – p. 7/3

  20. Carr and Wu (2004) • Monroe (1978) – p. 8/3

  21. Carr and Wu (2004) • Monroe (1978) • Stochastic Time change on Lévy Processes → stochastic volatility – p. 8/3

  22. Carr and Wu (2004) • Monroe (1978) • Stochastic Time change on Lévy Processes → stochastic volatility • Correlation between Lévy processes and random clock → leverage effect. – p. 8/3

  23. Carr and Wu (2004) • Monroe (1978) • Stochastic Time change on Lévy Processes → stochastic volatility • Correlation between Lévy processes and random clock → leverage effect. • Original clock as calendar time and new random clock as business time – p. 8/3

  24. Time-Change Now let t �→ T t , , t ≥ 0 , be an increasing RCLL process, such that for each fixed t , T t is a stopping time with respect to F . – p. 9/3

  25. Time-Change Now let t �→ T t , , t ≥ 0 , be an increasing RCLL process, such that for each fixed t , T t is a stopping time with respect to F . Furthermore, suppose T t is finite P − a.s., ∀ t ≥ 0 and T t → ∞ as t → ∞ . – p. 9/3

  26. Time-Change Now let t �→ T t , , t ≥ 0 , be an increasing RCLL process, such that for each fixed t , T t is a stopping time with respect to F . Furthermore, suppose T t is finite P − a.s., ∀ t ≥ 0 and T t → ∞ as t → ∞ . Then {T t } defines a random change on time, we can also impose E T t = t . – p. 9/3

  27. Time-Changed Lévy processes Then, consider the process Y t defined by: Y t ≡ X T t , t ≥ 0 , using different triplets for X and different time changes T t , we can obtain a good candidate for the underlying asset return process. . – p. 10/3

  28. Time-Changed Lévy processes Then, consider the process Y t defined by: Y t ≡ X T t , t ≥ 0 , using different triplets for X and different time changes T t , we can obtain a good candidate for the underlying asset return process. We know that if T t is an independent subordinator, then Y is a Lévy process. – p. 10/3

  29. Time-Changed Lévy processes Then, consider the process Y t defined by: Y t ≡ X T t , t ≥ 0 , using different triplets for X and different time changes T t , we can obtain a good candidate for the underlying asset return process. We know that if T t is an independent subordinator, then Y is a Lévy process. A more general situation is when T t is modeled by a non-decreasing semimartingale. – p. 10/3

  30. Time-Changed Lévy Processes In that case � t � ∞ T t = b t + yµ ( dy, ds ) 0 0 where b is a drift and µ is the counting measure of jumps of the time change and we can take µ = 0 and just take locally deterministic time changes, so we need to specify the local intensity ν : � t T t = ν ( s − ) ds (1) 0 where ν is the instantaneous activity rate, observe that ν must be non-negative. – p. 11/3

  31. Time-Changed Lévy Processes In that case � t � ∞ T t = b t + yµ ( dy, ds ) 0 0 where b is a drift and µ is the counting measure of jumps of the time change and we can take µ = 0 and just take locally deterministic time changes, so we need to specify the local intensity ν : � t T t = ν ( s − ) ds (2) 0 where ν is the instantaneous activity rate, observe that ν must be non-negative. – p. 11/3

  32. Remarks • When X t is the Brownian motion , ν is proportional to the instantaneous variance rate of the Brownian motion – p. 12/3

  33. Remarks • When X t is the Brownian motion , ν is proportional to the instantaneous variance rate of the Brownian motion • When X t is a pure jump Lévy process, ν is proportional to the Lévy intensity of jumps. – p. 12/3

  34. Time-Changed Lévy Processes We can obtain the characteristic function of Y t : � � �� φ Y t ( z ) = E ( e z ′ X T t ) = E e z ′ X u / T t = u . E – p. 13/3

  35. Time-Changed Lévy Processes We can obtain the characteristic function of Y t : � � �� φ Y t ( z ) = E ( e z ′ X T t ) = E e z ′ X u / T t = u . E If T t and X t were independent, then: φ Y t ( z ) = L T t ( ψ ( z )) where L T t is the Laplace transform of T t . – p. 13/3

  36. Time-Changed Lévy Processes So if the Laplace transform of T and the characteristic exponent of X have closed forms, we can obtain a closed form for φ Y t . Using equation (1) we have: R t L T t ( λ ) = E ( e − λ 0 ν ( s − ) ds ) (3) From bond pricing literature Carr and Wu (2004) obtained a closed forms for φ Y t . – p. 14/3

  37. Time-Changed Lévy Processes • When T is a Lévy processes the characteristics of Y are known explicitly. – p. 15/3

  38. Time-Changed Lévy Processes • When T is a Lévy processes the characteristics of Y are known explicitly. • When T has independent increments we can obtain a deterministic characteristics for Y . – p. 15/3

  39. Time-Changed Lévy Processes • When T is a Lévy processes the characteristics of Y are known explicitly. • When T has independent increments we can obtain a deterministic characteristics for Y . • When T is just a processes that turns Y in to a general semimartingale we can obtain a predictable version of the characteristics. – p. 15/3

  40. Model Consider a market model with three assets ( S 1 , S 2 , S 3 ) given by t = e Y 1 0 e Y 2 0 e Y 3 t , t , S 1 S 2 t = S 2 S 3 t = S 3 t (4) where ( Y 1 , Y 2 , Y 3 ) is a three dimensional Time-Changed Lévy process. – p. 16/3

Download Presentation
Download Policy: The content available on the website is offered to you 'AS IS' for your personal information and use only. It cannot be commercialized, licensed, or distributed on other websites without prior consent from the author. To download a presentation, simply click this link. If you encounter any difficulties during the download process, it's possible that the publisher has removed the file from their server.

Recommend


More recommend