costly public transfers in repeated cooperation under
play

Costly Public Transfers in Repeated Cooperation Under Imperfect - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

Costly Public Transfers in Repeated Cooperation Under Imperfect Monitoring Mikhail Panov and Sergey Vorontsov 1 / 23 Research Question Question: 2 / 23 Research Question Question: How can cartel members sustain collusion? 2 / 23 Research


  1. Costly Public Transfers in Repeated Cooperation Under Imperfect Monitoring Mikhail Panov and Sergey Vorontsov 1 / 23

  2. Research Question Question: 2 / 23

  3. Research Question Question: How can cartel members sustain collusion? 2 / 23

  4. Research Question Question: How can cartel members sustain collusion? By a threat of going into a price war. Under imperfect monitoring happens with probability 1; punishes everybody. 2 / 23

  5. Research Question Question: How can cartel members sustain collusion? By a threat of going into a price war. Under imperfect monitoring happens with probability 1; punishes everybody. In this paper How can transfers among cartel members help additionally sustain collusion? 2 / 23

  6. Model (based on Sannikov 2007) Two-player game in continuous time. 3 / 23

  7. Model (based on Sannikov 2007) Two-player game in continuous time. Imperfectly observable productive actions t P A 1 and A 2 A 1 t P A 2 3 / 23

  8. Model (based on Sannikov 2007) Two-player game in continuous time. Imperfectly observable productive actions t P A 1 and A 2 A 1 t P A 2 Public Brownian signal about these actions dX t “ µ p A 1 t , A 2 t q dt ` dZ t 3 / 23

  9. Model (based on Sannikov 2007) Two-player game in continuous time. Imperfectly observable productive actions t P A 1 and A 2 A 1 t P A 2 Public Brownian signal about these actions dX t “ µ p A 1 t , A 2 t q dt ` dZ t Expected profits under the play of A “ p A 1 , A 2 q 8 ż ” ˇ ı e ´ r p s ´ t q g i p A 1 t , A 2 W i t p A q “ E t t q ds ˇ A s , s P r t , 8s r ˇ t 3 / 23

  10. Model (based on Sannikov 2007) Observable costly transfers k P r 0 , 1 s — passthrough ratio; 4 / 23

  11. Model (based on Sannikov 2007) Observable costly transfers k P r 0 , 1 s — passthrough ratio; d Γ i t is sent by Player i at t ; k ¨ d Γ i t is received by Player ´ i at t ; 4 / 23

  12. Model (based on Sannikov 2007) Observable costly transfers k P r 0 , 1 s — passthrough ratio; d Γ i t is sent by Player i at t ; k ¨ d Γ i t is received by Player ´ i at t ; Γ 1 t and Γ 2 t are cumulative transfers until t . 4 / 23

  13. Model (based on Sannikov 2007) Observable costly transfers k P r 0 , 1 s — passthrough ratio; d Γ i t is sent by Player i at t ; k ¨ d Γ i t is received by Player ´ i at t ; Γ 1 t and Γ 2 t are cumulative transfers until t . Total expected payoffs under the play of p A , Γ q “ p A 1 , A 2 , Γ 1 , Γ 2 q 8 ż ” e ´ r p s ´ t q ´ ¯ˇ ı g i p A 1 t , A 2 t ` kd Γ ´ i W i t q ds ´ d Γ i t p A , Γ q “ E t ˇ A s , s P r t , 8s r ˇ t t 4 / 23

  14. Stage game and minimax payoffs 5 / 23

  15. Feasible profits 6 / 23

  16. Sannikov 2007 7 / 23

  17. Costly transfers for k “ 0 . 5 Player 1 sends $100 8 / 23

  18. This paper 9 / 23

  19. Supporting the best agreement, k=0 10 / 23

  20. Related Literature Collusion under imperfect monitoring Green and Porter 1984; Abreu, Pearce and Stachetti 1986; Fudenberg, Levine, and Maskin 1994; Sannikov 2007. Collusion with asymmetric punishments Harrington and Skrzypacz 2007. Repeated games with transfers Levine 2002; Goldluecke and Kranz 2012. Continuous games with observable actions Simon and Stinchcombe 1989; Bergin and MacLeod 1993; Hackbarth and Taub 2015. 11 / 23

  21. Main idea 12 / 23

  22. Main idea SPNE “ self-enforcing agreement. 12 / 23

  23. Main idea SPNE “ self-enforcing agreement. An agreement specifies productive actions and transfers after any history; players can publicly deviate in transfers; specifies continuations after observed deviations. 12 / 23

  24. Main idea SPNE “ self-enforcing agreement. An agreement specifies productive actions and transfers after any history; players can publicly deviate in transfers; specifies continuations after observed deviations. Strategies are defined only after an agreement is proposed! 12 / 23

  25. Agreement Money Burning case: k “ 0. 13 / 23

  26. Agreement Money Burning case: k “ 0. Fix a small ǫ ą 0. 13 / 23

  27. Agreement Money Burning case: k “ 0. Fix a small ǫ ą 0. An agreement recommends productive actions and transfer processes after any public history possible under it. 13 / 23

  28. Agreement Money Burning case: k “ 0. Fix a small ǫ ą 0. An agreement recommends productive actions and transfer processes after any public history possible under it. Each Player at any time can choose her hidden productive action; announce a deviation when she is required to transfer a positive amount of money, i.e. when E t p Γ i s q increases. 13 / 23

  29. Agreement Money Burning case: k “ 0. Fix a small ǫ ą 0. An agreement recommends productive actions and transfer processes after any public history possible under it. Each Player at any time can choose her hidden productive action; announce a deviation when she is required to transfer a positive amount of money, i.e. when E t p Γ i s q increases. Inertia Restriction: after a public deviation at p t , X t q , an agreement can not require transfers from the players until the first time s when |p s , X s q ´ p t , X t q| ě ǫ 13 / 23

  30. Agreement H is the set of public histories possible under the agreement. Inertia Restriction implies that at any history H t P H there will be only finitely many observed deviations. 14 / 23

  31. Agreement H is the set of public histories possible under the agreement. Inertia Restriction implies that at any history H t P H there will be only finitely many observed deviations. Let L p H t q be the subhistory of H t until the last public deviation. 14 / 23

  32. Agreement H is the set of public histories possible under the agreement. Inertia Restriction implies that at any history H t P H there will be only finitely many observed deviations. Let L p H t q be the subhistory of H t until the last public deviation. An agreement is a possibly infinite tree of leafs : each leaf is labeled by an element from L p H q ; each leaf specifies recommended productive action plans assuming there will be no further deviations. 14 / 23

  33. Agreement H is the set of public histories possible under the agreement. Inertia Restriction implies that at any history H t P H there will be only finitely many observed deviations. Let L p H t q be the subhistory of H t until the last public deviation. An agreement is a possibly infinite tree of leafs : each leaf is labeled by an element from L p H q ; each leaf specifies recommended productive action plans assuming there will be no further deviations. Stategy: Given an agreement, a strategy for Player i specifies within each leaf a productive action plan and a stopping time at which the player deviates. 14 / 23

  34. Promise keeping Within each leaf, promised continuation values satisfy dW i t “ r p W i t ´ g i p A t qq dt ´ rd Γ i t ` r β i ` dX t ´ µ p A t q dt q t for some vector-process β i . 15 / 23

  35. Profitable Deviations Instead of defining a payoff for each strategy, check only that there are no profitable deviations. 16 / 23

  36. Profitable Deviations Instead of defining a payoff for each strategy, check only that there are no profitable deviations. Sufficient to look only on finitely many observed deviations. 16 / 23

  37. Profitable Deviations Instead of defining a payoff for each strategy, check only that there are no profitable deviations. Sufficient to look only on finitely many observed deviations. When evaluating the gain, use upper Lesbegue integral. 16 / 23

  38. Incentive compatibility An agreement is self-enforcing if and only if the following two conditions hold 1 (One-stage DP in hidden actions) in all leafs and at all times @ a 1 i P A i , g i p A t q ` β i t µ p A t q ě g i p a 1 i , A ´ i t q ` β i t µ p a 1 i , A ´ i t q 2 (One-stage DP in observable actions) in all leafs at all times when a player can publicly deviate, her promised continuation value in the leaf following the deviation is no greater than on path. 17 / 23

  39. Solution K p ǫ q is the set of payoffs attainable in self-enforcing agreements. Let S be the set of payoffs attainable in Sannikov PPEs. Suppose that r is small enough, so that S has interior. Lemma 1: S Ă K p ǫ q . 18 / 23

  40. Solution K p ǫ q is the set of payoffs attainable in self-enforcing agreements. Let S be the set of payoffs attainable in Sannikov PPEs. Suppose that r is small enough, so that S has interior. Lemma 1: S Ă K p ǫ q . Lemma 2: K p ǫ q is convex and is above the minimax lines. 18 / 23

  41. Solution K p ǫ q is the set of payoffs attainable in self-enforcing agreements. Let S be the set of payoffs attainable in Sannikov PPEs. Suppose that r is small enough, so that S has interior. Lemma 1: S Ă K p ǫ q . Lemma 2: K p ǫ q is convex and is above the minimax lines. Lemma 3: For all sufficiently small ǫ , K p ǫ q is comprehensive. 18 / 23

  42. Solution Lemma 4: For all sufficiently small ǫ , at each point of B K p ǫ q that is not a static NE and that lies strictly above the minimax lines, Sannikov optimality equation is satisfied. 19 / 23

  43. Solution 20 / 23

  44. Solution 21 / 23

  45. Solution Lemma 5: For all sufficiently small ǫ , the curved part of B K p ǫ q meets the minimax lines either at a static NE or at a 90 degree angle. 22 / 23

  46. Solution 23 / 23

Download Presentation
Download Policy: The content available on the website is offered to you 'AS IS' for your personal information and use only. It cannot be commercialized, licensed, or distributed on other websites without prior consent from the author. To download a presentation, simply click this link. If you encounter any difficulties during the download process, it's possible that the publisher has removed the file from their server.

Recommend


More recommend