chapter 13 exchange rates business cycles and
play

Chapter 13 Exchange Rates, Business Cycles, and Macroeconomic - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

Chapter 13 Exchange Rates, Business Cycles, and Macroeconomic Policy in the Open Economy 1 Goals of Chapter 13 Two primary aspects of interdependence between economies of different nations International trade in goods and services


  1. Chapter 13 Exchange Rates, Business Cycles, and Macroeconomic Policy in the Open Economy 1

  2. Goals of Chapter 13 � Two primary aspects of interdependence between economies of different nations � International trade in goods and services � Worldwide integration of financial markets � Interdependence means that nations are dependent on each other, so policy changes in one country may affect other countries 2

  3. Topics in Chapter 13 13.1 Exchange Rates 13.2 How Exchange Rates are Determined: A Supply-and-Demand Analysis 13.3 The IS-LM Model for an Open Economy 13.4 Macroeconomic Policy in an Open Economy with Flexible Exchange Rates 13.5 Fixed Exchange Rates 3

  4. 13.1 Exchange Rates 4

  5. Nominal exchange rates � The nominal exchange rate tells you how much foreign currency you can obtain with one unit of the domestic currency � For example, if the nominal exchange rate is 110 yen per dollar, one dollar can be exchanged for 110 yen � Transactions between currencies take place in the foreign exchange market � Denote the nominal exchange rate (or simply, exchange rate) as e nom in units of the foreign currency per unit of domestic currency 5

  6. � Under a flexible-exchange-rate system or floating-exchange-rate system, exchange rates are determined by supply and demand and may change every day; this is the current system for major currencies 6

  7. � In the past, many currencies operated under a fixed-exchange-rate system, in which exchange rates were determined by governments � The exchange rates were fixed because the central banks in those countries offered to buy or sell the currencies at the fixed exchange rate � Examples include the gold standard, which operated in the late 1800s and early 1900s, and the Bretton Woods system, which was in place from 1944 until the early 1970s � Even today, though major currencies are in a flexible-exchange-rate system, some smaller countries fix their exchange rates 7

  8. Real Exchange Rates � The real exchange rate tells you how much of a foreign good you can get in exchange for one unit of a domestic good � If the nominal exchange rate is 110 yen per dollar, and it costs 1100 yen to buy a hamburger in Tokyo compared to 2 dollars in New York, the price of a U.S. hamburger relative to a Japanese hamburger is 0.2 Japanese hamburgers per U.S. hamburger 8

  9. � To simplify matters, we'll assume that each country produces a unique good � P ; price of domestic goods measured in the domestic currency � P For ; price of foreign goods measured in the foreign currency � The real exchange rate is the price of domestic goods relative to foreign goods, or (13.1) e = e nom P/P For � In reality, countries produce many goods, so we must use price indexes to get P and P For � If a country's real exchange rate is rising, its goods are becoming more expensive relative to the goods of the other country 9

  10. Appreciation and depreciation � In a flexible-exchange-rate system, when e nom falls, the domestic currency has undergone a nominal depreciation (or it has become weaker); when e nom rises, the domestic currency has become stronger and has undergone a nominal appreciation � In a fixed-exchange-rate system, a weakening of the currency is called a devaluation, a strengthening is called a revaluation � We also use the terms real appreciation and real depreciation to refer to changes in the real exchange rate 10

  11. Purchasing Power Parity � To examine the relationship between the nominal exchange rate and the real exchange rate, think first about a simple case in which all countries produce the same goods, which are freely traded � If there were no transportation costs, the real exchange rate would have to be e = 1, or else everyone would buy goods where they were cheaper � Setting e = 1 in Eq. (13.1) gives P = P For / e nom (13.2) � This means that similar goods have the same price in terms of the same currency, a concept known as purchasing power parity , or PPP 11

  12. � Empirical evidence shows that purchasing power parity holds in the long run but not in the short run because in reality, countries produce different goods, because some goods aren't traded, and because there are transportation costs and legal barriers to trade 12

  13. � When PPP doesn't hold, using Eq. (13.1), we can decompose changes in the real exchange rate into parts Δ e/e = Δ e nom / e nom + Δ P/P - Δ P For / P For � This can be rearranged as Δ e nom / e nom = Δ e/e + π For - π (13.3) � Thus a nominal appreciation is due to a real appreciation or a lower rate of inflation than in the foreign country 13

  14. � In the special case in which the real exchange rate doesn't change, so that Δ e/e = 0, the resulting equation in Eq. (13.3) is called relative purchasing power parity , since nominal exchange-rate movements reflect only changes in inflation � Relative purchasing power parity works well as a description of exchange-rate movements in high-inflation countries, since in those countries, movements in relative inflation rates are much larger than movements in real exchange rates 14

  15. McParity (Box 13.1) � As a test of the PPP hypothesis, the Economist magazine periodically reports on the prices of Big Mac hamburgers in different countries � The prices, when translated into dollar terms using the nominal exchange rate, range from just over $1 in Malaysia to almost $4 in Switzerland (using 1999 data), so PPP definitely doesn't hold � The hamburger price data forecasts movements in exchange rates � Hamburger prices might be expected to converge, so countries in which Big Macs are expensive may have a depreciation, while countries in which Big Macs are cheap may have an appreciation 15

  16. The real exchange rate and net exports � The real exchange rate (also called the terms of trade) is important because it represents the rate at which domestic goods and services can be traded for those produced abroad � An increase in the real exchange rate means people in a country can get more foreign goods for a given amount of domestic goods 16

  17. � The real exchange rate also affects a country's net exports (exports minus imports) � Changes in net exports have a direct impact on export and import industries in the country � Changes in net exports affect overall economic activity and are a primary channel through which business cycles and macroeconomic policy changes are transmitted internationally 17

  18. � The real exchange rate affects net exports through its effect on the demand for goods � A high real exchange rate makes foreign goods cheap relative to domestic goods, so there's a high demand for foreign goods (in both countries) � With demand for foreign goods high, net exports decline � Thus the higher the real exchange rate, the lower a country's net exports 18

  19. The J curve � The effect of a change in the real exchange rate may be weak in the short run and can even go the "wrong" way � Although a rise in the real exchange rate will reduce net exports in the long run, in the short run it may be difficult to quickly change imports and exports � As a result, a country will import and export the same amount of goods for a time, with lower relative prices on the foreign goods, thus increasing net exports 19

  20. � Similarly, a real depreciation will lead to a decline in net exports in the short run and a rise in the long run � This pattern of net exports is known as the J curve (Fig. 13.1) 20

  21. 21 Figure 13.01 The J curve

  22. ASSUMPTION The analysis in this chapter assumes a time period long enough that the movements along the J curve are complete, so that a real depreciation raises net exports and a real appreciation reduces net exports 22

  23. Application: The value of the dollar and U.S. net exports � Our theory suggests that the dollar and U.S. net exports should be inversely related � Looking at data since the early 1970s, when the world switched to floating exchange rates, confirms the theory, at least in the 1980s (text Fig. 13.2) 23

  24. Figure 13.02 The U.S. real exchange rate and net exports, 1973-2006 24

  25. � From 1980 to 1985 the dollar appreciated and net exports declined sharply � The dollar began depreciating in 1985, but it wasn't until late 1987 that net exports began to rise � Initially, economists relied on the J curve to explain the continued decline in net exports with the decline of the dollar � But two and one-half years is a long time for the J curve to be in effect 25

  26. � A possible explanation for this long lag in the J curve is a change in competitiveness � The strength of the dollar for such a long period in the first half of the 1980s meant U.S. firms lost many foreign customers � Foreign firms made many inroads into the United States � This is known as the "beachhead effect," because it allowed foreign producers to establish beachheads in the U.S. economy � In 1997-1998, net exports fell, reflecting the recessions experienced by U.S. trading partners, and the dollar strengthened 26

  27. 13.2 How Exchange Rates are Determined: A Demand-and-Supply Analysis 27

Download Presentation
Download Policy: The content available on the website is offered to you 'AS IS' for your personal information and use only. It cannot be commercialized, licensed, or distributed on other websites without prior consent from the author. To download a presentation, simply click this link. If you encounter any difficulties during the download process, it's possible that the publisher has removed the file from their server.

Recommend


More recommend