causal analysis within the framework of structural
play

Causal analysis within the framework of structural autoregressive - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

Causal analysis within the framework of structural autoregressive models Alessio Moneta Scuola Superiore SantAnna a.moneta@santannapisa.it Universitat Rovira i Virgili 13 February 2018 Outline 1. Why VAR models? 2. From VAR to SVAR


  1. Causal analysis within the framework of structural autoregressive models Alessio Moneta Scuola Superiore Sant’Anna a.moneta@santannapisa.it Universitat Rovira i Virgili 13 February 2018

  2. Outline 1. Why VAR models? 2. From VAR to SVAR models. 3. Problem of identification: two solutions based on causal search methods: ◮ Graphical Causal Models ◮ Independent Component Analysis

  3. Why VAR models?

  4. The Vector Autoregressive Model Given a vector y t of k variables: y t = µ t + D 1 y t − 1 + D 2 y t − 2 + . . . + D p y t − p + u t where D i are ( i = 1 , . . . , p ) are ( k × k ) matrices u t is a ( k × 1 ) vector of error terms (residuals), which are white noise and E ( u t u ′ t ) = Σ u . µ t is a ( k × 1 ) vector of constants (possibly including a deterministic trend). ⊲ Cfr. Sims, C. (1980) “Macroeconomics and Reality” Econometrica .

  5. Structural equations and causality ⊲ Cowles Commission Approach: dominant approach in macro-econometrics 1940s-1960s ◮ Haavelmo’s “The Probability Approach in Econometrics” (1944) ◮ Economic theory dictates the causal structure ◮ If the structure is adequate: error terms conform to standard probabilistic properties (independence and normality) ◮ Measuring the strengths of causal linkages.

  6. Example of structural model ⊲ Example: (Hoover 2006) m = α y + ε m (1) y = β m + ε y , (2) where m ≡ money, y ≡ GDP (both in logs). ⊲ Statistical properties of ε m and ε y tell whether the model is goods specified. ⊲ can we get α , β , ε m , ε y from the data? ⊲ Cfr. Hoover, K.D. (2006), “Economic Theory and Causal Inference”, in Handbook of the Philosophy of Economics .

  7. Example of structural model ⊲ Problem of identification solved introducing two exogenous variables: m = α y + δ r + ε m (3) y = β m + γ p + ε y , (4) where r ≡ interest rate, p ≡ price level (both in logs). ⊲ can we get α , β , δ , γ ε m , ε y from the data? ⊲ Yes. Model identified under the assumption that p is not a direct cause of m and r is not a direct cause of y ⊲ Omiting the error terms: r − → m ← → y ← − p

  8. Reduced form model ⊲ Afer substituting eq. (3) into eq. (4) and simplifying: αγ δ α 1 m = 1 − αβ p + 1 − αβ r + 1 − αβ ε m + 1 − αβ ε y (5) γ βδ β 1 y = 1 − αβ p + 1 − αβ r + 1 − αβ ε m + 1 − αβ ε y (6)

  9. Reduced form model ⊲ Afer substituting eq. (3) into eq. (4) and simplifying: αγ δ α 1 m = 1 − αβ p + 1 − αβ r + 1 − αβ ε m + 1 − αβ ε y (5) γ βδ β 1 y = 1 − αβ p + 1 − αβ r + 1 − αβ ε m + 1 − αβ ε y (6) ⊲ This system of reduced-form equations can be now estimated, since on the r.h.s. there are only exogenous variables: m = a p + b r + u m (7) y = c p + d r + u y (8)

  10. Reduced form model ⊲ Afer substituting eq. (3) into eq. (4) and simplifying: αγ δ α 1 m = 1 − αβ p + 1 − αβ r + 1 − αβ ε m + 1 − αβ ε y (5) γ βδ β 1 y = 1 − αβ p + 1 − αβ r + 1 − αβ ε m + 1 − αβ ε y (6) ⊲ This system of reduced-form equations can be now estimated, since on the r.h.s. there are only exogenous variables: m = a p + b r + u m (7) y = c p + d r + u y (8)

  11. Reduced form model ⊲ Afer substituting eq. (3) into eq. (4) and simplifying: αγ δ α 1 m = 1 − αβ p + 1 − αβ r + 1 − αβ ε m + 1 − αβ ε y (5) γ βδ β 1 y = 1 − αβ p + 1 − αβ r + 1 − αβ ε m + 1 − αβ ε y (6) ⊲ This system of reduced-form equations can be now estimated, since on the r.h.s. there are only exogenous variables: m = a p + b r + u m (7) y = c p + d r + u y (8)

  12. Reduced form model ⊲ Afer substituting eq. (3) into eq. (4) and simplifying: αγ δ α 1 m = 1 − αβ p + 1 − αβ r + 1 − αβ ε m + 1 − αβ ε y (5) γ βδ β 1 y = 1 − αβ p + 1 − αβ r + 1 − αβ ε m + 1 − αβ ε y (6) ⊲ This system of reduced-form equations can be now estimated, since on the r.h.s. there are only exogenous variables: m = a p + b r + u m (7) y = c p + d r + u y (8)

  13. Reduced form model ⊲ Afer substituting eq. (3) into eq. (4) and simplifying: αγ δ α 1 m = 1 − αβ p + 1 − αβ r + 1 − αβ ε m + 1 − αβ ε y (5) γ βδ β 1 y = 1 − αβ p + 1 − αβ r + 1 − αβ ε m + 1 − αβ ε y (6) ⊲ This system of reduced-form equations can be now estimated, since on the r.h.s. there are only exogenous variables: m = a p + b r + u m (7) y = c p + d r + u y (8)

  14. Reduced form model ⊲ Afer substituting eq. (3) into eq. (4) and simplifying: αγ δ α 1 m = 1 − αβ p + 1 − αβ r + 1 − αβ ε m + 1 − αβ ε y (5) γ βδ β 1 y = 1 − αβ p + 1 − αβ r + 1 − αβ ε m + 1 − αβ ε y (6) ⊲ This system of reduced-form equations can be now estimated, since on the r.h.s. there are only exogenous variables: m = a p + b r + u m (7) y = c p + d r + u y (8)

  15. Reduced form model ⊲ Afer substituting eq. (3) into eq. (4) and simplifying: αγ δ α 1 m = 1 − αβ p + 1 − αβ r + 1 − αβ ε m + 1 − αβ ε y (5) γ βδ β 1 y = 1 − αβ p + 1 − αβ r + 1 − αβ ε m + 1 − αβ ε y (6) ⊲ This system of reduced-form equations can be now estimated, since on the r.h.s. there are only exogenous variables: m = a p + b r + u m (7) y = c p + d r + u y (8) a , ˆ c , ˆ ⊲ From the OLS estimates ˆ b , ˆ d , ˆ u m , ˆ u y , using the respective

  16. Reduced form model ⊲ Afer substituting eq. (3) into eq. (4) and simplifying: αγ δ α 1 m = 1 − αβ p + 1 − αβ r + 1 − αβ ε m + 1 − αβ ε y (5) γ βδ β 1 y = 1 − αβ p + 1 − αβ r + 1 − αβ ε m + 1 − αβ ε y (6) ⊲ This system of reduced-form equations can be now estimated, since on the r.h.s. there are only exogenous variables: m = a p + b r + u m (7) y = c p + d r + u y (8) a , ˆ c , ˆ ⊲ From the OLS estimates ˆ b , ˆ d , ˆ u m , ˆ u y , using the respective

  17. Instrumental variables ⊲ Notice that the structural-form coefficients ( α, β in the ex.) could be equivalently obtained by instrumental variables estimation. ⊲ Following the previous example: ◮ p : instrumental variable for eq. (1) ( m = α y + ε m ) ◮ r : instrumental variable for eq. (2) ( y = β m + ε y ) ⊲ Two-stage least squares estimation for eq. (1): 1 OLS regression of y on p : obtain ˆ y 2 OLS regression of m on ˆ y : obtain ˆ α IV

  18. Summary on Structural Equation Modeling ⊲ SEM: provide quantitative assessment of cause-effect relationships. ⊲ Interpretation of causality: ◮ counterfactual ◮ manipulability ⊲ Probabilistic methods are used to measure causality and partially to test it, but not for the sake of causal discovery. ⊲ Dependence on a priori economic theory: ◮ necessity of identifying restrictions. ⊲ Empiricist query: where does the economic theory come from?

  19. The crisis of the Cowles Commission approach ⊲ Up to the 1970s: consensus on the Cowles Commission approach ◮ Important economic events in the 1970s: Oil crisis (1973), stagflation. Increasing skepticism towards so-called “Keynesian Macroeconomics”. ⊲ Two major critiques: ◮ Lucas Critique (1976) on economic policy evaluation structural equations are ineffective for policy evaluation: they are unstable under intervention ◮ Sims (1980) article Macroeconomics and Reality restrictions used in the Cowles Commission approach are incredible, i.e. empirically not validated ⊲ Cfr. Favero, C.A. (2001) Applied Macroeconometrics , OUP.

  20. The crisis of the Cowles Commission approach Reactions to the criticisms: ⊲ Change the theory maintaining the structural, theory-driven approach ◮ cfr. New Classical Macroeconomics (Lucas, Sargent), and rational expectations models ◮ even more extreme theory-driven approach: calibration ⊲ Adopt a more data-driven approach: Time-series econometric models, more intensive use of statistical methods ◮ Granger Causality (1969) ◮ Vector Autoregressive Models (VAR) (Sims 1980)

  21. Granger causality Consider two time series X t and Y t . The idea of Granger’s (1969, 1980) causality: ◮ { Y t } causes { X t } if Y t helps to predict X t + h . Definition (G.-causality, Granger 1980: 330 ): ◮ Y t is said to cause X t + 1 if P ( X t + 1 ∈ A | Ω t ) � = P ( X t + 1 ∈ A | Ω t \ Y t ) , for a set A and for a set Ω t of “relevant information” available at time t ( Ω t \ Y t := relevant information except Y t ). Merely probabilistic notion of causality. Importance to appraise usefulness of G-causality but differences with structural causality.

  22. T esting G-non-causality Granger non-causality (GNC) tests: ◮ Regression of X t + 1 on Ω t (including X t , Y t and their lagged values) + same regression excluding Y t (and its lagged values). ◮ Check error variances of the two regressions (with and without Y t ); and/or ◮ Test whether the Y t coefficients in the regression of X t + 1 on Ω t are zero ( F or t test).

  23. Structural vs. G-causality (Example from Hoover 2001: 151) Suppose the unobserved structural model (DGP) is: Y t = θ X t + β 11 Y t − 1 + β 12 X t − 1 + ǫ 1 t (9) X t = γ Y t + β 21 Y t − 1 + β 22 X t − 1 + ǫ 2 t (10) Reduced form model: Y t = a 11 Y t − 1 + a 12 X t − 1 + ν 1 t (11) X t = a 21 Y t − 1 + a 22 X t − 1 + ν 2 t , (12) (coefficients in (11)-(12) are functions of coefficients in (9)-(10)) GNC tests: ◮ if a 12 = 0, then X does not G-causes Y ◮ if a 21 = 0, then Y does not G-causes X .

Download Presentation
Download Policy: The content available on the website is offered to you 'AS IS' for your personal information and use only. It cannot be commercialized, licensed, or distributed on other websites without prior consent from the author. To download a presentation, simply click this link. If you encounter any difficulties during the download process, it's possible that the publisher has removed the file from their server.

Recommend


More recommend