admission fees in auctions
play

admission fees in auctions Jiafeng (Kevin) Chen and Scott Duke - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

admission fees in auctions Jiafeng (Kevin) Chen and Scott Duke Kominers October 14, 2018 Ec 2099 Harvard University Seller prefers N Value of market power bulow and klemperer 1996 Assume symmetric values Given the choice of:


  1. admission fees in auctions Jiafeng (Kevin) Chen and Scott Duke Kominers October 14, 2018 Ec 2099 Harvard University

  2. Seller prefers N “Value of market power bulow and klemperer 1996 • Assume symmetric values • Given the choice of: Which should the seller prefer? Theorem (Bulow and Klemperer 1996) 1 bidders and second-price auction with no reserve. Value of thickness” Seller should increase participation 1 • N + 1 bidders, but English auction with no reserve • N bidders, but revenue-maximizing mechanism

  3. “Value of market power bulow and klemperer 1996 • Assume symmetric values • Given the choice of: Which should the seller prefer? Theorem (Bulow and Klemperer 1996) reserve. Value of thickness” Seller should increase participation 1 • N + 1 bidders, but English auction with no reserve • N bidders, but revenue-maximizing mechanism Seller prefers N + 1 bidders and second-price auction with no

  4. bulow and klemperer 1996 • Assume symmetric values • Given the choice of: Which should the seller prefer? Theorem (Bulow and Klemperer 1996) reserve. Seller should increase participation 1 • N + 1 bidders, but English auction with no reserve • N bidders, but revenue-maximizing mechanism Seller prefers N + 1 bidders and second-price auction with no ⇒ “Value of market power ≤ Value of thickness” ⇝

  5. • Consider the intermediate mechanism: Run optimal proof sketch (kirkegaard 2006) • So constrained optimal mechanism must be weakly better 1 auction on N English Intermediate mechanism Optimal on N • (Myerson 1981) 1 bidders is constrained optimal • English auction on N • Allocates object with probability 1 • A mechanism is constrained optimal if it is revenue • Same revenue as the optimal mechanism on N bidders. not sold. 1 st bidder if mechanism on N bidders. Give object to N the optimal mechanism on N bidders 1 bidders beats • A constrained optimal mechanism on N probability 1. maximizing, constrained on the object being sold with 2

  6. • Consider the intermediate mechanism: Run optimal proof sketch (kirkegaard 2006) • English auction on N 1 auction on N English Intermediate mechanism Optimal on N • (Myerson 1981) 1 bidders is constrained optimal • Allocates object with probability 1 • So constrained optimal mechanism must be weakly better • A mechanism is constrained optimal if it is revenue • Same revenue as the optimal mechanism on N bidders. not sold. 1 st bidder if mechanism on N bidders. Give object to N the optimal mechanism on N bidders probability 1. maximizing, constrained on the object being sold with 2 • A constrained optimal mechanism on N + 1 bidders beats

  7. proof sketch (kirkegaard 2006) • English auction on N 1 auction on N English Intermediate mechanism Optimal on N • (Myerson 1981) 1 bidders is constrained optimal • So constrained optimal mechanism must be weakly better • A mechanism is constrained optimal if it is revenue • Allocates object with probability 1 • Same revenue as the optimal mechanism on N bidders. not sold. the optimal mechanism on N bidders probability 1. maximizing, constrained on the object being sold with 2 • A constrained optimal mechanism on N + 1 bidders beats • Consider the intermediate mechanism: Run optimal mechanism on N bidders. Give object to ( N + 1 ) st bidder if

  8. proof sketch (kirkegaard 2006) • English auction on N 1 auction on N English Intermediate mechanism Optimal on N • (Myerson 1981) 1 bidders is constrained optimal • So constrained optimal mechanism must be weakly better • A mechanism is constrained optimal if it is revenue • Allocates object with probability 1 • Same revenue as the optimal mechanism on N bidders. not sold. the optimal mechanism on N bidders probability 1. maximizing, constrained on the object being sold with 2 • A constrained optimal mechanism on N + 1 bidders beats • Consider the intermediate mechanism: Run optimal mechanism on N bidders. Give object to ( N + 1 ) st bidder if

  9. proof sketch (kirkegaard 2006) • English auction on N 1 auction on N English Intermediate mechanism Optimal on N • (Myerson 1981) 1 bidders is constrained optimal • So constrained optimal mechanism must be weakly better • A mechanism is constrained optimal if it is revenue • Allocates object with probability 1 • Same revenue as the optimal mechanism on N bidders. not sold. the optimal mechanism on N bidders probability 1. maximizing, constrained on the object being sold with 2 • A constrained optimal mechanism on N + 1 bidders beats • Consider the intermediate mechanism: Run optimal mechanism on N bidders. Give object to ( N + 1 ) st bidder if

  10. proof sketch (kirkegaard 2006) not sold. (Myerson 1981) • So constrained optimal mechanism must be weakly better • Allocates object with probability 1 • A mechanism is constrained optimal if it is revenue • Same revenue as the optimal mechanism on N bidders. the optimal mechanism on N bidders probability 1. maximizing, constrained on the object being sold with 2 • A constrained optimal mechanism on N + 1 bidders beats • Consider the intermediate mechanism: Run optimal mechanism on N bidders. Give object to ( N + 1 ) st bidder if • English auction on N + 1 bidders is constrained optimal • = ⇒ Optimal on N = Intermediate mechanism < English auction on N + 1

  11. a puzzle Figure 1: “CHARITY AUCTIONS: 12+ INSANELY USEFUL TIPS FOR YOUR AUCTION,” OneCause Fundraising Solutions. https://www.onecause.com/charity-auction/ 3

  12. model with entry • Submit bids What should the seller choose? • N potential bidders 0 1 potential bidders but • N New question: Given the choice of • Bidders see value after entering Two-stage mechanism • Auction • Potential bidders i • Entry decisions 4 • Entering costs a random c i (Drive to the auction site) • Seller can choose to institute fee φ • Cost of entrance is c i + φ for potential bidder i

  13. model with entry Two-stage mechanism • Entry decisions • Potential bidders i • Auction • Bidders see value after entering • Submit bids New question: Given the choice of • N potential bidders What should the seller choose? 4 • Entering costs a random c i (Drive to the auction site) • Seller can choose to institute fee φ • Cost of entrance is c i + φ for potential bidder i • N + 1 potential bidders but φ = 0

  14. N potential bidders. Cost c i are i.i.d. 0.05 0.00 0.05 0.10 0.15 Revenue advantage of admission fee Theoretical value of admission fee advantage Plot the revenue advantage of 95% -confidence interval 0.20 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 N Figure 2: is better for large N our result Theorem as a function of N 1 bidders Revenue with N Revenue with : 1 . N 1 Set (not necessarily optimal) fee Exponential with mean N . Uniform 0 1 . Values are i.i.d. Proof by simulation. the extra potential bidder. 5 Under certain conditions, the seller prefers φ > 0 rather than

  15. 0.05 0.00 0.05 0.10 0.15 Revenue advantage of admission fee Theoretical value of admission fee advantage 95% -confidence interval 0.20 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 N Figure 2: is better for large N our result Theorem as a function of N 1 Set (not necessarily optimal) fee Exponential with mean N . Proof by simulation. the extra potential bidder. 5 Under certain conditions, the seller prefers φ > 0 rather than N potential bidders. Cost c i are i.i.d. Uniform [ 0 , 1 ] . Values are i.i.d. φ = N − 1 . Plot the revenue advantage of φ : ( Revenue with φ ) − ( Revenue with N + 1 bidders )

  16. our result Exponential with mean N . Theorem as a function of N 1 Set (not necessarily optimal) fee 5 the extra potential bidder. Proof by simulation. Under certain conditions, the seller prefers φ > 0 rather than N potential bidders. Cost c i are i.i.d. 0.05 Uniform [ 0 , 1 ] . Values are i.i.d. 0.00 0.05 φ = 0.10 N − 1 . 0.15 Revenue advantage of admission fee Plot the revenue advantage of φ : Theoretical value of admission fee advantage 95% -confidence interval 0.20 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 ( Revenue with φ ) N − ( Revenue with N + 1 bidders ) Figure 2: φ is better for large N

  17. • Single bidder, Uniform 0 1 value, willingness to pay is 1 • If bidder knew his value, optimal reserve is 1 • Seller collects 1 optimal revenue is 1 2 half the time • Bidder gains 1 4 “information edge” by observing his value. 4 . intuitions 2 . before knowing the value. 2 • Charging bidders up front puts a price on information • Seller is a monopolist selling seats to the auction • Extra potential bidder may not enter 6 Reasons for seller to prefer φ > 0:

  18. • Single bidder, Uniform 0 1 value, willingness to pay is 1 • If bidder knew his value, optimal reserve is 1 • Seller collects 1 optimal revenue is 1 2 half the time • Bidder gains 1 4 “information edge” by observing his value. 4 . intuitions 2 . before knowing the value. 2 • Charging bidders up front puts a price on information • Seller is a monopolist selling seats to the auction • Extra potential bidder may not enter 6 Reasons for seller to prefer φ > 0:

Download Presentation
Download Policy: The content available on the website is offered to you 'AS IS' for your personal information and use only. It cannot be commercialized, licensed, or distributed on other websites without prior consent from the author. To download a presentation, simply click this link. If you encounter any difficulties during the download process, it's possible that the publisher has removed the file from their server.

Recommend


More recommend