a general theory of backward stochastic difference
play

A General Theory of Backward Stochastic Difference Equations Robert - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

A General Theory of Backward Stochastic Difference Equations A General Theory of Backward Stochastic Difference Equations Robert J. Elliott and Samuel N. Cohen University of Adelaide and University of Calgary July 2, 2009 A General Theory of


  1. A General Theory of Backward Stochastic Difference Equations A General Theory of Backward Stochastic Difference Equations Robert J. Elliott and Samuel N. Cohen University of Adelaide and University of Calgary July 2, 2009

  2. A General Theory of Backward Stochastic Difference Equations Outline Dynamic Nonlinear Expectations Discrete BSDEs Binomial Pricing Existence & Uniqueness A Comparison Theorem BSDEs and Nonlinear Expectations Conclusions

  3. A General Theory of Backward Stochastic Difference Equations Risk and Pricing ◮ A key question in Mathematical Finance is: Given a future random payoff X, what are you willing to pay today for X? ◮ One could also ask “How risky is X?” ◮ Various attempts have been made to answer this question. (Expected utility, CAPM, Convex Risk Measures, etc...) ◮ While giving an axiomatic approach to answering this question, we shall outline the theory of “Backward Stochastic Difference Equations.”

  4. A General Theory of Backward Stochastic Difference Equations Recall: A filtered probability space consists of (Ω , F , {F t } , P ) , where ◮ Ω is the set of all outcomes ◮ F is the set of all events ◮ F t is the set of all events known at time t ◮ P gives the probability of each event The set L 2 ( F t ) is those random variables, with finite variance, that are known at time t . A statement about outcomes is an event A ∈ F . It is said to hold P -a.s. if P ( statement is true ) = P ( ω : ω ∈ A ) = 1 .

  5. A General Theory of Backward Stochastic Difference Equations Dynamic Nonlinear Expectations Nonlinear Expectations For some terminal time T , we define an ‘ F t -consistent nonlinear expectation’ E to be a family of operators E ( ·|F t ) : L 2 ( F T ) → L 2 ( F t ); t ≤ T with 1. (Monotonicity) If Q 1 ≥ Q 2 P -a.s., E ( Q 1 |F t ) ≥ E ( Q 2 |F t ) 2. (Constants) For all F t -measurable Q , E ( Q |F t ) = Q

  6. A General Theory of Backward Stochastic Difference Equations Dynamic Nonlinear Expectations Nonlinear Expectations 3. (Recursivity) For s ≤ t , E ( E ( Q |F t ) |F s ) = E ( Q |F s ) 4. (Zero-One law) For any A ∈ F t , E ( I A Q |F t ) = I A E ( Q |F t ) .

  7. A General Theory of Backward Stochastic Difference Equations Dynamic Nonlinear Expectations Nonlinear Expectations Two other properties are desirable 5. (Translation invariance) For any q ∈ L 2 ( F t ) , E ( Q + q |F t ) = E ( Q |F t ) + q . 6. (Concavity) For any λ ∈ [ 0 , 1 ] , E ( λ Q 1 + ( 1 − λ ) Q 2 |F t ) ≥ λ E ( Q 1 |F t ) + ( 1 − λ ) E ( Q 2 |F t )

  8. A General Theory of Backward Stochastic Difference Equations Dynamic Nonlinear Expectations Nonlinear Expectations There is a relation between nonlinear expectations and convex risk measures: ◮ If (1)-(6) are satisfied, then for each t , ρ t ( X ) := −E ( X |F t ) defines a dynamic convex risk measure. These risk measures are time consistent . ◮ For simplicity, this presentation will discuss nonlinear expectations. ◮ How could we construct such a family of operators?

  9. A General Theory of Backward Stochastic Difference Equations Dynamic Nonlinear Expectations Recall: ◮ A process M is called adapted if M t is known at time t (i.e. M t is F t measurable). ◮ A martingale difference process is an adapted process M such that, for all t , E [ M t |F t − 1 ] = 0 . and E � M t � < + ∞ .

  10. A General Theory of Backward Stochastic Difference Equations Discrete BSDEs ◮ In this presentation, we shall consider discrete time processes satisfying ‘Backward Stochastic Difference Equations’. ◮ These are the natural extension of Backward Stochastic Differential Equations in continuous time. ◮ We shall see that every nonlinear expectation satisfying Axioms (1-5) solves a BSDE with certain properties, and conversely. ◮ We also establish necessary and sufficient conditions for concavity (Axiom 6). ◮ To do this, we first need to set up our probability space.

  11. A General Theory of Backward Stochastic Difference Equations Discrete BSDEs A probabilistic setting ◮ Let X be a discrete time, finite state process. Without loss of generality, X takes values from the unit vectors in R N . ◮ Let {F t } be the filtration generated by X , that is F t consists of every event that can be known from watching X up to time t . ◮ Let M t = X t − E [ X t |F t − 1 ] . Then M is a martingale difference process, that is E [ M t |F t − 1 ] = 0 ∈ R N .

  12. A General Theory of Backward Stochastic Difference Equations Discrete BSDEs Discrete BSDEs (‘D=Difference’) A BSDE is an equation of the form: � � Y t − F ( ω, u , Y u , Z u ) + Z u M u + 1 = Q t ≤ u < T t ≤ u < T ◮ Q is the terminal condition (in R ) ◮ F is a (stochastic) ‘driver’ function, with F ( ω, u , · , · ) known at time u . ◮ A solution is an adapted pair ( Y , Z ) of processes, Y t ∈ R and Z t ∈ R N × 1 . ◮ All quantities are assumed to be P -a.s. finite.

  13. A General Theory of Backward Stochastic Difference Equations Discrete BSDEs Discrete BSDEs (‘D=Difference’) Equivalently, we can write this in a differenced form: Y t − F ( ω, t , Y t , Z t ) + Z t M t + 1 = Y t + 1 with terminal condition Y T = Q . The important detail is that ◮ The terminal condition is fixed, and the dynamics are given in reverse. ◮ The solution ( Y , Z ) is adapted, that is, at time t it depends only on what has happened up to time t .

  14. A General Theory of Backward Stochastic Difference Equations Discrete BSDEs Binomial Pricing A Special Case: Binomial Pricing ◮ Suppose we have a market with two assets: a stock Y following a simple binomial price process, and a risk free Bond B . ◮ Let r t denote the one-step interest rate at time t . ◮ From each time t , there are two possible states for the stock price the following day, Y ( t + 1 , ↑ ) and Y ( t + 1 , ↓ ) . ◮ Suppose these two states occur with (real world) probabilities p and 1 − p respectively.

  15. A General Theory of Backward Stochastic Difference Equations Discrete BSDEs Binomial Pricing It is easy to show that there exists a unique ‘no-arbitrage’ price 1 Y ( t ) = [ π Y ( t + 1 , ↑ ) + ( 1 − π ) Y ( t + 1 , ↓ )] 1 + r t 1 = E π [ Y ( t + 1 ) |F t ] . 1 + r t Here π the ‘risk-neutral probability’, that is, the price today is the average discounted price tomorrow; when π is the probability of a price increase. We know that π is not dependent on the real world – it is simply a mathematical object which we calculate using the stock price, π = ( 1 + r t ) Y ( t ) − Y ( t + 1 , ↓ ) Y ( t + 1 , ↑ ) − Y ( t + 1 , ↓ ) .

  16. A General Theory of Backward Stochastic Difference Equations Discrete BSDEs Binomial Pricing Writing Y t = Y ( t ) etc... we also know, Y t + 1 = E p ( Y t + 1 |F t ) + L t + 1 where E p ( Y t + 1 |F t ) is the (real-world) conditional mean value of Y t + 1 , and L t + 1 is a random variable with conditional mean value zero ( L t + 1 = Y t + 1 − E p ( Y t + 1 |F t )) .

  17. A General Theory of Backward Stochastic Difference Equations Discrete BSDEs Binomial Pricing In the notation we established before, we can define a Martingale difference process M � 1 − p � − p � � M t + 1 ( ↑ ) = , M t + 1 ( ↓ ) = . p − 1 p And it is easy to show that L t + 1 can be written as Z t · M t + 1 , for some row vector Z t known at time t .

  18. A General Theory of Backward Stochastic Difference Equations Discrete BSDEs Binomial Pricing We can then do some basic algebra: Y t + 1 = E p ( Y t + 1 |F t ) + L t + 1 = Y t + r t Y t − ( 1 + r t ) Y t + E p ( Y t + 1 |F t ) + Z t M t + 1 1 = Y t + r t Y t − ( 1 + r t ) E π ( Y t + 1 |F t ) + E p ( Y t + 1 |F t ) + Z t M t + 1 1 + r t = Y t + r t Y t − E π ( Y t + 1 − E p ( Y t + 1 ) |F t ) + Z t M t + 1 = Y t + r t Y t − E π ( L t + 1 |F t ) + Z t M t + 1 � � = Y t − − r t Y t + Z t E π ( M t + 1 |F t ) + Z t M t + 1 = Y t − F ( Y t , Z t ) + Z t M t + 1

  19. A General Theory of Backward Stochastic Difference Equations Discrete BSDEs Binomial Pricing So our one-step pricing formula is equivalent to the equation Y t + 1 = Y t − F ( Y t , Z t ) + Z t M t + 1 where F ( Y t , Z t ) = − r t Y t + Z t · E ( M t + 1 |F t ) � π − 0 . 5 � = − r t Y t + Z t . 0 . 5 − π This is a special case of a BSDE.

  20. A General Theory of Backward Stochastic Difference Equations Discrete BSDEs Existence & Uniqueness Before giving general existence properties of BSDEs, we need the following. Definition t M t + 1 P -a.s. for all t , then we write Z 1 ∼ M Z 2 . If Z 1 t M t + 1 = Z 2 Note this is an equivalence relation for Z t ∈ R N × 1 . Theorem For any F t + 1 -measurable random variable W ∈ R with E [ W |F t ] = 0 , there exists a F t -measurable Z t ∈ R N × 1 with W = Z t M t + 1 .

  21. A General Theory of Backward Stochastic Difference Equations Discrete BSDEs Existence & Uniqueness An Existence Theorem Theorem (Cohen & Elliott, forthcoming) Suppose (i) F ( ω, t , Y t , Z t ) is invariant under equivalence ∼ M (ii) For all Z t , the map Y t �→ Y t − F ( ω, t , Y t , Z t ) is a bijection Then a BSDE with driver F has a unique solution. Corollary These conditions are necessary and sufficient.

Download Presentation
Download Policy: The content available on the website is offered to you 'AS IS' for your personal information and use only. It cannot be commercialized, licensed, or distributed on other websites without prior consent from the author. To download a presentation, simply click this link. If you encounter any difficulties during the download process, it's possible that the publisher has removed the file from their server.

Recommend


More recommend