18 175 lecture 27 more on martingales
play

18.175: Lecture 27 More on martingales Scott Sheffield MIT 18.175 - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

18.175: Lecture 27 More on martingales Scott Sheffield MIT 18.175 Lecture 27 1 Outline Conditional expectation Martingales Arcsin law, other SRW stories 18.175 Lecture 27 2 Outline Conditional expectation Martingales Arcsin law, other SRW stories


  1. 18.175: Lecture 27 More on martingales Scott Sheffield MIT 18.175 Lecture 27 1

  2. Outline Conditional expectation Martingales Arcsin law, other SRW stories 18.175 Lecture 27 2

  3. Outline Conditional expectation Martingales Arcsin law, other SRW stories 18.175 Lecture 27 3

  4. Recall: conditional expectation Say we’re given a probability space (Ω , F 0 , P ) and a σ -field � � F ⊂ F 0 and a random variable X measurable w.r.t. F 0 , with E | X | < ∞ . The conditional expectation of X given F is a new random variable, which we can denote by Y = E ( X |F ). We require that Y is F measurable and that for all A in F , � � we have � XdP = � YdP . A A Any Y satisfying these properties is called a version of � � E ( X |F ). Theorem: Up to redefinition on a measure zero set, the � � random variable E ( X |F ) exists and is unique. This follows from Radon-Nikodym theorem. � � 18.175 Lecture 27 4

  5. Conditional expectation observations Linearity: E ( aX + Y |F ) = aE ( X |F ) + E ( Y |F ). � � If X ≤ Y then E ( E |F ) ≤ E ( Y |F ). � � If X n ≥ 0 and X n ↑ X with EX < ∞ , then E ( X n |F ) ↑ E ( X |F ) � � (by dominated convergence). If F 1 ⊂ F 2 then � � � E ( E ( X |F 1 ) |F 2 ) = E ( X |F 1 ). � E ( E ( X |F 2 ) |F 1 ) = E ( X |F 1 ). Second is kind of interesting: says, after I learn F 1 , my best � � guess of what my best guess for X will be after learning F 2 is simply my current best guess for X . Deduce that E ( X |F i ) is a martingale if F i is an increasing � � sequence of σ -algebras and E ( | X | ) < ∞ . 18.175 Lecture 27 5

  6. Outline Conditional expectation Martingales Arcsin law, other SRW stories 18.175 Lecture 27 6

  7. Outline Conditional expectation Martingales Arcsin law, other SRW stories 18.175 Lecture 27 7

  8. Martingales Let F n be increasing sequence of σ -fields (called a filtration ). � � A sequence X n is adapted to F n if X n ∈ F n for all n . If X n is � � an adapted sequence (with E | X n | < ∞ ) then it is called a martingale if E ( X n +1 |F n ) = X n for all n . It’s a supermartingale (resp., submartingale ) if same thing holds with = replaced by ≤ (resp., ≥ ). 18.175 Lecture 27 8

  9. Martingale observations Claim: If X n is a supermartingale then for n > m we have � � E ( X n |F m ) ≤ X m . Proof idea: Follows if n = m + 1 by definition; take � � n = m + k and use induction on k . Similar result holds for submartingales. Also, if X n is a � � martingale and n > m then E ( X n |F m ) = X m . Claim: if X n is a martingale w.r.t. F n and φ is convex with � � E | φ ( X n ) | < ∞ then φ ( X n ) is a submartingale. Proof idea: Immediate from Jensen’s inequality and � � martingale definition. Example: take φ ( x ) = max { x , 0 } . � � 18.175 Lecture 27 9

  10. Predictable sequence Call H n predictable if each H + n is F n − 1 measurable. � � Maybe H n represents amount of shares of asset investor has at � � n th stage. n Write ( H · X ) n = � H m ( X m − X m − 1 ). � � m =1 Observe: If X n is a supermartingale and the H n ≥ 0 are � � bounded, then ( H · X ) n is a supermartingale. Example: take H n = 1 N ≥ n for stopping time N . � � 18.175 Lecture 27 10

  11. Two big results Optional stopping theorem: Can’t make money in � � expectation by timing sale of asset whose price is non-negative martingale. Proof: Just a special case of statement about ( H · X ) if � � stopping time is bounded. Martingale convergence: A non-negative martingale almost � � surely has a limit. Idea of proof: Count upcrossings (times martingale crosses a � � fixed interval) and devise gambling strategy that makes lots of money if the number of these is not a.s. finite. Basically, you buy every time price gets below the interval, sell each time it gets above. Stronger convergence statement: If X n is a submartingale � � + < ∞ then as n → ∞ , X + n converges a.s. to a with sup EX n limit X with E | X | < ∞ . 18.175 Lecture 27 11

  12. Other statements If X n is a supermartingale then as n → ∞ , X n → X a.s. and � � EX ≤ EX 0 . Proof: Y n = − X n ≤ 0 is a submartingale with EY + = 0. � � Since EX 0 ≥ EX n , inequality follows from Fatou’s lemma. Doob’s decomposition: Any submartingale X n can be � � written in a unique way as X n = M n + A n where M n is a martingale and A n is a predictable increasing sequence with A 0 = 0. Proof idea: Just let M n be sum of “surprises” (i.e., the � � values X n − E ( X n |F n − 1 )). A martingale with bounded increments a.s. either converges to � � limit or oscillates between ±∞ . That is, a.s. either lim X n < ∞ exists or lim sup X n = + ∞ and lim inf X n = −∞ . 18.175 Lecture 27 12

  13. Problems How many primary candidates does one expect to ever exceed � � 20 percent on Intrade? (Asked by Aldous.) Compute probability of having a martingale price reach a � � before b if martingale prices vary continuously. Polya’s urn: r red and g green balls. Repeatedly sample � � randomly and add extra ball of sampled color. Ratio of red to green is martingale, hence a.s. converges to limit. 18.175 Lecture 27 13

  14. Wald Wald’s equation: Let X i be i.i.d. with E | X i | < ∞ . If N is a � � stopping time with EN < ∞ then ES N = EX 1 EN . Wald’s second equation: Let X i be i.i.d. with E | X i | = 0 and � � 2 = σ 2 < ∞ . If N is a stopping time with EN < ∞ then EX i ES N = σ 2 EN . 18.175 Lecture 27 14

  15. Wald applications to SRW S 0 = a ∈ Z and at each time step S j independently changes � � by ± 1 according to a fair coin toss. Fix A ∈ Z and let N = inf { k : S k ∈ { 0 , A } . What is E S N ? What is E N ? � � 18.175 Lecture 27 15

  16. Outline Conditional expectation Martingales Arcsin law, other SRW stories 18.175 Lecture 27 16

  17. Outline Conditional expectation Martingales Arcsin law, other SRW stories 18.175 Lecture 27 17

  18. Reflection principle How many walks from (0 , x ) to ( n , y ) that don’t cross the � � horizontal axis? Try counting walks that do cross by giving bijection to walks � � from (0 , − x ) to ( n , y ). 18.175 Lecture 27 18

  19. Ballot Theorem Suppose that in election candidate A gets α votes and B gets � � β < α votes. What’s probability that A is ahead throughout the counting? Answer: ( α − β ) / ( α + β ). Can be proved using reflection � � principle. 18.175 Lecture 27 19

  20. Arcsin theorem Theorem for last hitting time. � � Theorem for amount of positive positive time. � � 18.175 Lecture 27 20

  21. MIT OpenCourseWare http://ocw.mit.edu 18.175 Theory of Probability Spring 2014 For information about citing these materials or our Terms of Use, visit: http://ocw.mit.edu/terms.

Download Presentation
Download Policy: The content available on the website is offered to you 'AS IS' for your personal information and use only. It cannot be commercialized, licensed, or distributed on other websites without prior consent from the author. To download a presentation, simply click this link. If you encounter any difficulties during the download process, it's possible that the publisher has removed the file from their server.

Recommend


More recommend