semi parametric pricing and hedging of volatility and
play

Semi-parametric Pricing and Hedging of Volatility and Hybrid - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

Semi-parametric Pricing and Hedging of Volatility and Hybrid Derivatives Peter Carr Based on work with Roger Lee and Matt Lorig Department Chair, Finance & Risk Engineering, Tandon School, NYU Pricing of exotic derivatives: parametric


  1. Semi-parametric Pricing and Hedging of Volatility and Hybrid Derivatives Peter Carr Based on work with Roger Lee and Matt Lorig Department Chair, Finance & Risk Engineering, Tandon School, NYU

  2. Pricing of exotic derivatives: parametric approach The parametric approach for valuing exotic derivatives involves: • specifying parametric risk-neutral dynamics for the spot price S of an underlying asset (e.g., Black Scholes, CEV, Heston, SABR, Hull-White, MJD, Variance Gamma, CGMY, . . . ), • calibrating the parameters to liquid market prices of puts P ( K i , T j ) & calls C ( K i , T j ) , typically by a least squares fit, • valuing exotics (either analytically or numerically) under the specification using the calibrated parameters. This approach has a number of shortcomings: • parametric models rarely exactly fit market data, • the parameters can be difficult to identify and the calibration procedure is often computationally intensive. As time evolves, the fit worsens, requiring re-calibration, • to speed up the (re-)calibration, the dynamical specification is often chosen to produce closed-form call/put prices, but these are rare and possibly far from market prices.

  3. Pricing of exotic derivatives: non-parametric approach The non-parametric approach to pricing exotics involves: • specifying non-parametric risk-neutral dynamics for the underlying spot price S (e.g., under zero rates & dividends, S is a driftless diffusion or a positive continuous martingale), • converting discrete strike/maturity option prices into arbitrage-free curves P/C ( T ) , P/C ( K ) , or surfaces P/C ( K, T ) , • deriving upper and/or lower bounds for exotic derivative prices consistent with the curve or surface. Sometimes, the bounds meet, eg. for (continuously monitored) variance swaps relative to P/C ( K ) . This approach has some possible shortcomings: • difficult to interpolate/extrapolate P/C ( K i , T j ) arbitrage-free. • sub and super-replication strategies typically rule out dynamic trading in options ex ante; thereby widening the no arbitrage bounds. The resulting lower and upper bounds may be too far apart to use as the bid and ask price of the exotic.

  4. Pricing of exotic derivatives: semi-parametric approach The semi-parametric approach we use can be outlined as follows: • specify part of the risk-neutral dynamics of S parametrically, with the rest specified non-parametrically, • when the exotic’s payoff depends on [ln S ] T and possibly also S T , we get unique prices and hedges relative to given co-terminal European call prices C ( K ) and put prices P ( K ) . This approach has a number of advantages: • compared to parametric models , semi-parametric models are more flexible and therefore more likely to fit market data, • compared to the typical usage of non-parametric models , our replicating strategy allows dynamic trading in calls and puts, causing the upper and lower bounds on value to meet.

  5. Basic assumptions and notation Throughout this talk, we make the following assumptions: • no arbitrage, • no transactions costs, • zero interest rates/dividends. We fix a maturity date T . Denote by S = ( S t ) 0 ≤ t ≤ T the price of a strictly positive risky asset. Denote by X = ( X t ) 0 ≤ t ≤ T the ln price: X t = ln S t . Under the above assumptions, put and call prices are given by P ( K ) = E ( K − S T ) + , C ( K ) = E ( S T − K ) + . Here, E denotes expectation with respect to the market’s chosen risk-neutral pricing measure Q . We assume a call and/or put trades at every strike K ∈ (0 , ∞ ) .

  6. Non-parametric pricing of Path-Independent Payoffs Carr and Madan (1998) show that, if f can be expressed as the difference of convex functions, then for any κ ∈ R + , we have � ( s − κ ) + − ( κ − s ) + � f ( s ) = f ( κ ) + f ′ ( κ ) � κ � ∞ d Kf ′′ ( K )( K − s ) + + d Kf ′′ ( K )( s − K ) + . + 0 κ Replacing s with S T , setting κ = S 0 , and taking an expectation � S 0 � ∞ d Kf ′′ ( K ) P ( K ) + d Kf ′′ ( K ) C ( K ) . E f ( S T ) = f ( S 0 ) + 0 S 0 Takeaway : the price of any path-independent payoff E f ( S T ) can be expressed relative to market prices of puts and calls on S T . This result makes no assumptions on the dynamics of the spot price process S . To price path-dependent payoffs, we need to impose some structure on the risk-neutral dynamics of S .

  7. Our Semi-parametric model On a filtered probability space (Ω , F , F , P ) the underlying asset’s spot price S solves: � (e z − 1) S t − � d S t = σ t S t d W t + N (d t, d z ) , R � N (d t, d z ) = N (d t, d z ) − ν (d z )d t, • W is a Brownian motion under the risk-neutral pricing measure Q , with respect to (w.r.t.) the filtration F = ( F t ) 0 ≤ t ≤ T . • � N is a compensated Poisson random measure w.r.t. Q . • The volatility process σ evolves independently of S , W , and � N . The model is semi-parametric in that: • The vol process σ is non-parametric ( σ need not be Markov, eg. fractional Brownian motion w. unknown Hurst parameter, and may jump with unknown intensity/jump size). • We specify the risk-neutral L´ evy measure ν parametrically.

  8. Framework allows for asymmetric implied volatility smiles 0.35 0.30 0.25 0.20 0.15 - 1.0 - 0.5 0.5 1.0 Imp. vol as a function of ln -moneyness-to-maturity for T = { 1 , 2 , 3 } months. � � z � d X t = γ ( Z t )d t + Z t d W t + N (d t, d z ) , R � d Z t = κ ( θ − Z t )d t + δ Z t d B t , � − ( z − m ) 2 � 1 ν (d z ) = √ 2 πs 2 exp d z. 2 s 2

  9. Types of claims we consider By Itˆ o’s Lemma, the process X := ln S satisfies d X t = − 1 2 σ 2 t d t + σ t d W t � � (e z − 1 − z ) ν (d z )d t + z � − N (d t, d z ) . R R We wish to price and hedge hybrid claims of the form Payoff at time T = ϕ ( X T , [ X ] T ) , [ X ] T = realized quadratic variation of X up to time T. Examples Variance Swap : ϕ ( X T , [ X ] T ) = [ X ] T , � Volatility Swap : ϕ ( X T , [ X ] T ) = [ X ] T , � Sharpe Ratio : ϕ ( X T , [ X ] T ) = ( X T − X 0 ) / [ X ] T . We also consider options on Leveraged ETFs, which are path-dependent claims on X , but whose payoff cannot be written simply as ϕ ( X T , [ X ] T ) .

  10. Pricing exponential claims We use exponential claims as a basis for more general claims. e i ωX T + i s [ X ] T exponential claim payoff : To this end, the following proposition will be useful. Proposition Define u : C 2 → C and ψ : C 2 → C as � � � 4 − ω 2 − i ω + 2 i s − 1 1 u ( ω, s ) := i 2 ± , � � � e i ωz + i sz 2 − 1 − i ω (e z − 1) ψ ( ω, s ) := ν (d z ) . R Then the joint characteristic function of ( X T , [ X ] T ) given F t is = e ( T − t ) ψ ( ω,s )+ i ( ω − u ( ω,s )) X t + i s [ X ] t E t e i ωX T + i s [ X ] T E t e i u ( ω,s ) X T . � �� � � �� � e ( T − t ) ψ ( u ( ω,s ) , 0) � �� � Path-dep. claim Path-ind. claim F t -measurable

  11. Key ingredients of proof X can be separated into a continuous component and an independent jump component d X t = d X c t + d X j t , d X c t = − 1 2 σ 2 t d t + σ t W t , � � (e z − 1 − z ) ν (d z )d t + d X j z � t = − N (d t, d z ) . R R Carr and Lee (2008) show that the continuous component ( X c , [ X c ]) satisfies E t e i ω ( X c T − X c t )+ i s ([ X c ] T − [ X c ] t ) = E t e i u ( ω,s )( X c T − X c t ) . The jump component ( X j , [ X j ]) is a two-dimensional L´ evy process with joint characteristic exponent ψ E t e i ω ( X j T − X j t )+ i s ([ X j ] T − [ X j ] t ) = e ( T − t ) ψ ( ω,s ) ,

  12. Proof Using results from the previous page, we have E t e i ω ( X T − X t )+ i s ([ X ] T − [ X ] t ) = E t e i ω ( X c T − X c t )+ i s ([ X c ] T − [ X c ] t ) E t e i ω ( X j T − X j ( X c ⊥ t )+ i s ([ X j ] T − [ X j ] t ) ⊥ X j ) = E t e i u ( ω,s )( X c T − X c t ) (Carr Lee result ) e ( T − t ) ψ ( ω,s ) ( ( X j , [ X j ]) is L´ evy) = E t e i u ( ω,s )( X T − X t ) ( X c ⊥ t ) e ( T − t ) ψ ( ω,s ) ⊥ X j ) E t e i u ( ω,s )( X j T − X j = E t e i u ( ω,s )( X T − X t ) ( X j is L´ e ( T − t ) ψ ( u ( ω,s ) , 0) e ( T − t ) ψ ( ω,s ) . evy) Thus, we obtain E t e i ωX T + i s [ X ] T = e − i u ( ω,s ) X t e i ωX t + i s [ X ] t e ( T − t ) ψ ( ω,s ) E t e i u ( ω,s ) X T . e ( T − t ) ψ ( u ( ω,s ) , 0)

  13. Pricing power-exponential claims We can use previous result to price power-exponential claims E t X n T [ X ] m T e i ωX T + i s [ X ] T � �� � power-exponential claim price = ( − i ∂ ω ) n ( − i ∂ s ) m E t e i ωX T + i s [ X ] T = ( − i ∂ ω ) n ( − i ∂ s ) m e ( T − t ) ψ ( ω,s )+ i ( ω − u ( ω,s )) X t + i s [ X ] t E t e i u ( ω,s ) X T e ( T − t ) ψ ( u ( ω,s ) , 0) � �� � =: F ( ω,s,X t , [ X ] t ) � n �� m � n m � � ( − i ∂ ω ) j ( − i ∂ s ) k F ( ω, s, X t , [ X ] t ) = j k j =0 � �� � k =0 F t -measurable × E t ( − i ∂ ω ) n − j ( − i ∂ s ) m − k e i u ( ω,s ) X T � �� � Path-independent claim price

  14. Example: variance swap Effect of jump size Effect of jump intensity 10 8 6 6 4 4 2 2 0.5 1.0 1.5 2.0 0.5 1.0 1.5 2.0 - 2 We plot g (ln s ) as a function of s where E g (ln S T ) = E [ln S ] T , ν (d z ) = λδ m ( z )d z, T = 0 . 25 , S 0 = 1 . Left : λ = 1 . 00 , m = {− 2 . 00 , 0 , 2 . 00 } , Right : m = − 2 . 00 , λ = { 1 . 00 , 2 . 00 , 3 . 00 } .

Download Presentation
Download Policy: The content available on the website is offered to you 'AS IS' for your personal information and use only. It cannot be commercialized, licensed, or distributed on other websites without prior consent from the author. To download a presentation, simply click this link. If you encounter any difficulties during the download process, it's possible that the publisher has removed the file from their server.

Recommend


More recommend