portfolio selection with estimation risk a test based
play

Portfolio Selection with Estimation Risk: a Test-based Approach - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

The 11th Annual Financial Econometrics Conference "Econometric Modeling in Risk Management" Portfolio Selection with Estimation Risk: a Test-based Approach Bertille Antoine Simon Fraser University, Vancouver March 27th, 2009


  1. The 11th Annual Financial Econometrics Conference "Econometric Modeling in Risk Management" Portfolio Selection with Estimation Risk: a Test-based Approach Bertille Antoine Simon Fraser University, Vancouver March 27th, 2009

  2. INTRODUCTION • How to choose the optimal portfolio? or the best allocation between available risky assets and the riskless asset? → depends on the performance measure Q examples: mean-variance, Sharpe-ratio... • Q depends on characteristics of returns distributions → true characteristics are unknown • 2-step procedure: (1) maximize Q � you get an infeasible optimal portfolio (2) plug-in � use estimates to make it feasible –2–

  3. • Main issues: → Estimation risk overlooked ie the fact that true (unknown) characteristics � = estimated ones (finite sample size...) → "Optimality" of this 2-step approach? –3–

  4. THIS PAPER : ⋆ Integrated portfolio selection method that accounts for estimation risk → 1-step procedure → Feasible investment rule (no plug-in required) ⋆ Allocations compared through their probability of beating a benchmark ⋆ For reasonable benchmarks, the definition of optimality is more conservative ⋆ Of interest for several industries, e.g. pension funds, mutual funds → Very general procedure –4–

  5. Main results: - when performance measure Q is mean-variance - when estimation risk of variance is ignored ⋆ Theoretical results : - Closed-form optimal allocation - No nuisance parameter - No suboptimal plug-in step - Reinterpretation of our investor as a mean-variance investor → with a corrected, sample-dependent risk-aversion parameter ⋆ Practical results : (for reasonable benchmarks): - Simulation & Empirical study: very good performance → especially small sample sizes → stable investment rule –5–

  6. OUTLINE I - P-value investment rule II - Related literature III - Theoretical comparisons IV - Practical comparisons V - Conclusion –6–

  7. I - P-VALUE INVESTMENT RULE ⋆ Perform a one-sided test ensuring the portfolio performance is above a given threshold: H 0 : Q > c ⋆ Maximize the associated p-value to get optimal weights: � � P ( ˆ θ p = arg max Q ( θ ) > c ) θ • Why a test? - Statistical tool to compare random quantities - Automatically incorporates estimation risk - Well-defined objective function for portfolio manager –7–

  8. • Very general procedure - Any performance measure Q - Any (consistent) estimate ˆ Q • Simplifications and Assumptions - Portfolio performance evaluated by mean-variance criterion - Estimation risk of the variance neglected (number of assets over sample size kept small) - Asymptotic test (for tractability) • Formally: - N risky assets iid (mean µ and variance Σ ) and the riskfree asset - θ vector of weights invested in the risky assets µ − η - Mean-variance performance: Q MV = θ ′ ˜ 2 θ ′ Σ θ → How to choose θ according to Q MV ? –8–

  9. • Classical Mean-Variance problem (Markowitz) - 2-step plug-in method � � /η ⇒ ˆ θ MV = [ˆ Σ − 1 ˆ Σ − 1 ˜ max θ [ Q MV ] ⇒ θ MV = µ µ ] /η ˜ ⋆ 2-fund rule: - [ˆ Σ − 1 ˆ µ ] = sample tangency portfolio allocates wealth among risky assets ˜ - η = risk-aversion parameter weights the share of wealth assigned to risky assets • P-value rule for a benchmark c : � � � Q MV (ˆ θ MV ) ˆ Σ − 1 ˆ max θ [ P ( Q MV > c )] ⇒ θ p ( c ) = µ ˜ / ˜ η p with ˜ η p = η c ⋆ 2-fund rule with corrected risk-aversion parameter Interpretation: Favorable financial environment (i.e. sample with high performance) then (likely) c < Q MV (ˆ θ MV ) and ˜ η p > η i.e. decrease the share invested in risky assets –9–

  10. • How to choose the benchmark? - Not really a choice variable → determined heterogeneously → historic performance - Still we can define the (mathematical) optimal benchmark Definition: maximize the expected portfolio performance associated with the optimal p-value rule θ p ( c ) for a benchmark c � � �� 2 µ ′ ˆ Σ − 1 ˜ ˆ ˜ µ 0 √ E c ∗ = 1 γ 2 γ 2 ≡ ˆ µ ′ ˆ ˆ Σ − 1 ˆ 2 η × ˆ ˜ ˜ � � ˆ �� 2 µ where µ ′ ˆ Σ − 1 ˆ Σ − 1 Σ 0 ˆ ˜ µ ˜ E γ 2 ˆ → c ∗ is unfeasible → Without estimation risk: θ p ( c ∗ ) = θ MV –10–

  11. II - RELATED LITERATURE • Dealing with Estimation risk: ◮ Frequentist ◮ Axiomatic ◮ Bayesian –11–

  12. ◮ Frequentist: Minimize the loss function of replacing the true (unknown) mean of the portfolio by its sample estimate → very complicated problem → restriction to the class of 2-fund rules - ter Horst, de Roon and Werker (2006): ignore estimation risk of variance - Kan and Zhou (2007): incorporate both estimation risks also they consider the class of 3-fund rules (add sample global mean-variance portfolio) → All rules are unfeasible → Additional (non-optimal) plug-in step required –12–

  13. ◮ Axiomatic (Garlappi, Uppal and Wang (2007)): - Sequential min-max approach i.e. max. the worst performance - Standard MV framework modified by adding a preliminary minimization step: . Restrict expected returns to fall into CI around estimated value . Minimize over the possible expected returns subject to this constraint - Solid axiomatic foundation: → model allows multi priors and the investor is averse to ambiguity → but sequentiality cannot be directly liked to an optimality criterion ◮ Bayesian (Bawa, Brown and Klein (1979)): - Maximize the expected portfolio performance: expectation computed according to the predictive distribution (= combination of historical observations and the prior) - Unknown parameters = random variables → Uninformative priors –13–

  14. • Investment rules: ◮ Feasible rules (both for simulated and empirical data) - P1: P-value with target 10% Optimum or MV-CE - P2: P-value with target 50% Optimum or MV-CE - P3: P-value with target 90% Optimum or MV-CE - EQ: Equi-weighted portfolio - MV: Feasible counterpart of MV 0 - B: Bayesian with diffuse priors - KZ: Feasible counterpart of KZ 0 - HRW: Feasible counterpart of HRW 0 - KZ3: Feasible counterpart of KZ 3 0 - GUW: Garlappi, Uppal and Wang ◮ Infeasible rules (only for simulated data) - MV 0 : (infeasible) Mean-variance - KZ 0 : Kan and Zhou (infeasible) 2-fund - HRW 0 : ter Horst, de Roon and Werker (infeasible) 2-fund - KZ 3 0 : Kan and Zhou (infeasible) 3-fund –14–

  15. III - THEORETICAL COMPARISONS • Theoretical rankings derived by Kan and Zhou (2007): � � B >> MV � � MV 0 >> KZ 3 0 >> KZ 0 � HRW 0 � � � GUW >> means "outperforms in terms of expected mean-variance performance" → In practice: unfeasible rules need to be estimated → Theoretical ranking not guaranteed anymore –15–

  16. • Reinterpretation of investment rules ⋆ Feasible mean-variance rule: ˆ θ MV = [ˆ Σ − 1 ˆ µ ] /η ˜ . [ˆ Σ − 1 ˆ µ ] sample tangency portfolio allocates wealth among risky assets ˜ . η = risk-aversion parameter weights the share of wealth assigned to risky assets ⋆ Any 2-fund rule = mean-variance rule with corrected risk-aversion � Literature: ˜ η KZ > ˜ η HRW > η and ˜ η B > η � This paper : ˜ η p more flexible depending on realized sample: - if c > Q MV then ˜ η p < η - if c < Q MV then ˜ η p > η Interpretation: moderate benchmark & profitable financial environment (ie a sample associated to a relatively high performance) → smaller part invested in the risky assets → avoid extreme positions –16–

  17. IV - COMPARATIVE STUDY • Design: - Rolling window approach: window of size 120 (ie 10 years of monthly data) → Series of (monthly) out-of-sample returns for each strategy k - Compare strategies according to: ⋆ Out-of-sample Sharpe-ratio (SR): ˆ ˜ µ k � SR k = ˆ σ k ⋆ Out-of-sample certainty-equivalent return (CE): µ k − η � CE k = ˆ σ 2 ˜ 2 ˆ k ⋆ Portfolio turnover: T − 1 � 1 ( | θ k,t +1 − θ k,t | ) ′ ι Turnover k = T − T w − 1 t = T w +1 where ι is the column vector of ones of size N . –17–

  18. • Monte-Carlo study: ⋆ DGP: - Asset returns generated according to a distribution F that deviates slightly from the normal distribution F = (1 − h ) N + hD - Generate the joint normal distribution N through factor model with 4 risky assets including 1 factor, and 1 riskless asset - 3 different proportions h : no deviation; 2.5%; 5% - 3 different deviation distributions D (i) deterministic: expected return of the asset plus 5 standard deviations; (ii) binomial: expected return of the asset plus 5 standard deviations with prob. 0.5 and to the expected return of the asset minus 5 standard deviations with prob. 0.5; (iii) normal distribution with mean equal to the expected return of the asset plus 5 standard deviations and same covariance matrix as N . –18–

Download Presentation
Download Policy: The content available on the website is offered to you 'AS IS' for your personal information and use only. It cannot be commercialized, licensed, or distributed on other websites without prior consent from the author. To download a presentation, simply click this link. If you encounter any difficulties during the download process, it's possible that the publisher has removed the file from their server.

Recommend


More recommend