financial econometrics econ 40357 constant expected
play

Financial Econometrics Econ 40357 Constant expected return model and - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

Financial Econometrics Econ 40357 Constant expected return model and efficient market hypothesis N.C. Mark University of Notre Dame and NBER October 11, 2020 1 / 12 Textbook Brooks pp. 334-351. Brooks pp. 586-588. 2 / 12 Efficient Market


  1. Financial Econometrics Econ 40357 Constant expected return model and efficient market hypothesis N.C. Mark University of Notre Dame and NBER October 11, 2020 1 / 12

  2. Textbook Brooks pp. 334-351. Brooks pp. 586-588. 2 / 12

  3. Efficient Market Hypothesis and Testable Implications Statement of the hypothesis Current price of asset ‘reflects’ all currently available public information. 1 Implies you shouldn’t be able to systematically predict future returns and earn 2 abnormal profits based on publically available information. When there is news, it gets incorporated into asset prices immediately. 3 Let I t be information set at t . Then, E ( r t + 1 | I t ) = 0 Testable implications. Let r t be the return on an asset or portfolio of assets, and x t be a vector of publically available information. Then β in the regression should be zero. r t + 1 = α + β ′ x t + ǫ t + 1 ǫ t + 1 is uncorrelated (orthogonal) to I t 3 / 12

  4. Test Efficient Market Hypothesis What to use for x t ? How about past returns? 1 Fama, for many years (in the 70s and 80s, the biggest proponent of efficient 2 markets hypothesis. Then Fama himself uncovered violations of the hypothesis, with multiperiod 3 returns. What about multiperiod returns? If it’s true for one-period ahead, it must be true for 4 multiperiod returns. 4 / 12

  5. Dividend yield as predictor 1 P is the stock price (not log price), d is the dividend (not log). β = 1 + ρ is the subjective discount factor, ρ is the discount rate. Present value model, ∞ β j d t + j P t = E t ∑ j = 0 Let’s say we expect dividends to grow at rate δ each period, so that E t d t + 1 = ( 1 + δ ) d t ( 1 + δ ) j d t E t d t + j = and ρ > δ . Then 5 / 12

  6. Dividend yield as predictor (theory) � 1 + δ � 1 + ρ � j ∞ ∞ � ∑ β j d t + j = ∑ P t = E t d t = d t 1 + ρ ρ − δ j = 0 j = 0 � 1 + ρ � E t P t + 1 = ( 1 + δ ) d t ρ − δ � 1 + ρ � ( 1 + δ ) 2 d t E t P t + 2 = ρ − δ � 1 + ρ P t + 1 � ( 1 + δ ) d t = E t ρ − δ P t P t � 1 + ρ P t + 2 � ( 1 + δ ) 2 d t = E t P t ρ − δ P t Must be the case that � 1 + ρ P t + k � ( 1 + δ ) k d t = E t P t ρ − δ P t Dividend yield predicts future returns. Slope gets bigger as horizon increases. 6 / 12

  7. Famous finance regression d t r t , t + k = α + β k + ǫ t , t + k (1) P t where r t , t + k is the k − period ahead future return on the stock market, d t / P t is the current period dividend yield on the market. Fama and French, Campbell and Shiller ran these regressions long ago. There are two points First, that returns are predictable Second, because the dividend yield moves around, the risk premium (on the market) varys over time. Before running this regression, we want to know if the dividend yield is stationary, or if it has a unit root. Let’s do it! with lh dy.wf1. Note also that the predictive regression for k > 1 will induce serial correlation in regression error terms. Standard errors need to be estimated by Newey-West. The results reject the random walk hypothesis for stock prices. 7 / 12

  8. Dividend yield and 12-month ahead 1-year return 8 / 12

  9. Dividend yield and 96-month ahead 8-year return 9 / 12

  10. ‘Overlapping’ observations in regression Let r 1 , t = p t − p t − 1 and let x t = d t / P t be the dividend yield. The efficient markets idea is E t ( r 1 , t + 1 ) = β 1 x t r 1 , t + 1 = β 1 x t + ǫ t + 1 ǫ t + 1 not realized until t + 1, and is uncorrelated (orthogonal) to all information available at t . Suppose process driving dividend yield is x t = ρ x t − 1 + u t iid ∼ ( 0 , σ 2 u ) . Then where 0 < ρ < 1, and u t r 1 , t + 2 = β 1 x t + 1 + ǫ t + 2 = β 1 ρ x t + ǫ t + 2 + β 1 u t + 1 10 / 12

  11. r t + 1 = β 1 x t + ǫ t + 1 r t + 2 = β 1 x t + 1 + ǫ t + 1 = β 1 ( ρ x t + u t + 1 ) + ǫ r + 1 y t + 2 = r t + 1 + r t + 2 = β 1 ( 1 + ρ ) x t + ǫ t + 2 + ǫ t + 1 + β 1 u t + 1 y t + 3 = r t + 2 + r t + 3 = β 1 ( 1 + ρ ) x t + 1 + ǫ t + 3 + ǫ t + 2 + β 1 u t + 2 Solution: Newey-West t-ratios 11 / 12

  12. Two additional points There are variables that forecast stock returns. � d t � R e t + k , t = α + β + ǫ t + k P t Plot dividend yield against the 7 year return. If you bought stocks in 1980, great! Bought stocks in 2000–not so good. Code: LHret DY plot.m . Lesson is, E t R e t + k , t varies a lot. Expected excess returns are large and variable . Why? The 1970s economy was terrible. Since 2008, the economy has been terrible. In the bad state, people have low tolerance for risk. But isn’t P high because people forecast high dividend growth? Evidence says no! Prices are high relative to dividends because people expect low future returns. Prices move around dividends. Dividends don’t move around prices. Prices are high (dividend yield low) when people are willing to hold risk (expansion/boom). Prices are low (dividend yield high) when people unwilling to bear risk (recession). 12 / 12

Download Presentation
Download Policy: The content available on the website is offered to you 'AS IS' for your personal information and use only. It cannot be commercialized, licensed, or distributed on other websites without prior consent from the author. To download a presentation, simply click this link. If you encounter any difficulties during the download process, it's possible that the publisher has removed the file from their server.

Recommend


More recommend