ec400 part ii math for micro lecture 3
play

EC400 Part II, Math for Micro: Lecture 3 Leonardo Felli NAB.SZT 13 - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

EC400 Part II, Math for Micro: Lecture 3 Leonardo Felli NAB.SZT 13 September 2010 Sufficient Conditions for Global Optimum Second order sufficient conditions for global maximum (minimum) in R n : Suppose that x is a critical point of a


  1. EC400 Part II, Math for Micro: Lecture 3 Leonardo Felli NAB.SZT 13 September 2010

  2. Sufficient Conditions for Global Optimum Second order sufficient conditions for global maximum (minimum) in R n : Suppose that x ∗ is a critical point of a function f ( x ) with continuous first and second order partial derivatives on R n . Then x ∗ is: A global maximizer (minimizer) for f ( x ) if D 2 f ( x ) is negative (positive) semi-definite on R n . A strict global maximizer (minimizer) for f ( x ) if D 2 f ( x ) is negative (positive) definite on R n . Leonardo Felli (LSE, NAB.SZT) EC400 Part II, Math for Micro: Lecture 3 13 September 2010 2 / 23

  3. Why are concave functions so useful in economics? The property that critical points of concave functions are global maximizers is an important one in economic theory. Recall: Definition A real valued function f defined on a convex subset U of R n is concave, if for all x , y in U and for all t ∈ [0 , 1] : f ( t x + (1 − t ) y ) ≥ t f ( x ) + (1 − t ) f ( y ) Leonardo Felli (LSE, NAB.SZT) EC400 Part II, Math for Micro: Lecture 3 13 September 2010 3 / 23

  4. Theorem Let f 1 , ..., f k be concave functions, each defined on the same convex subset U of R n . Let a 1 , a 2 , ..., a k be positive numbers. Then a 1 f 1 + a 2 f 2 + ... + a k f k is a concave function on U . Proof of Theorem Consider x ∈ U, y ∈ U, and t ∈ [0 , 1] . Let k = 2 , then: a 1 f 1 ( t x + (1 − t ) y ) + a 2 f 2 ( t x + (1 − t ) y ) ≥ a 1 [ t f 1 ( x ) + (1 − t ) f 1 ( y )] + a 2 [ t f 2 ( x ) + (1 − t ) f 2 ( y )] ≥ t [ a 1 f 1 ( x ) + a 2 f 2 ( x )] + (1 − t ) [ a 1 f 1 ( y ) + a 2 f 2 ( y )] Leonardo Felli (LSE, NAB.SZT) EC400 Part II, Math for Micro: Lecture 3 13 September 2010 4 / 23

  5. Application Consider a firm’s profit maximization. The firm’s production function is y = g ( x ), where y denotes output and x denote the input bundle. Let p denote the price of output and w i the per-unit cost of input i , then the firm’s profit function is Π( x ) = p g ( x ) − ( w 1 x 1 + w 2 x 2 + ... + w n x n ) The result above implies that the profit function is concave if the production function is concave. Leonardo Felli (LSE, NAB.SZT) EC400 Part II, Math for Micro: Lecture 3 13 September 2010 5 / 23

  6. It follows from the concavity of − ( w 1 x 1 + w 2 x 2 + ... + w n x n ) and the concavity of g plus the result above. The first order conditions are p ∂ g = w i for i = 1 , 2 , ..., n . ∂ x i Concavity of the firm’s profit function implies that they are both necessary and sufficient for an interior profit maximizer. Leonardo Felli (LSE, NAB.SZT) EC400 Part II, Math for Micro: Lecture 3 13 September 2010 6 / 23

  7. Preliminaries Definition The level k set of function f defined on U in R n is: X f k = { x ∈ U | f ( x ) = k } This could be a point, a curve, a plane or an hyperplane. Leonardo Felli (LSE, NAB.SZT) EC400 Part II, Math for Micro: Lecture 3 13 September 2010 7 / 23

  8. Quasi-Concavity Definition A function f defined on a convex subset U of R n is quasi-concave if for every real number k , C + k = { x ∈ U | f ( x ) ≥ k } is a convex set. In other words, for any level k the set of points in the function domain that map to values of the function greater of equal than k is a convex set. Alternatively, the level sets of the function bound convex subsets from below. Leonardo Felli (LSE, NAB.SZT) EC400 Part II, Math for Micro: Lecture 3 13 September 2010 8 / 23

  9. Example: Quasi-Concave Function f ( x ) ✻ f ( x ) k ✲ x b a 0 Leonardo Felli (LSE, NAB.SZT) EC400 Part II, Math for Micro: Lecture 3 13 September 2010 9 / 23

  10. Example: Quasi-Concave Function F ( x , y ) = xy y ✻ F ( x , y ) = k ′ , k ′ > k F ( x , y ) = k ✲ x 0 Leonardo Felli (LSE, NAB.SZT) EC400 Part II, Math for Micro: Lecture 3 13 September 2010 10 / 23

  11. Quasi-Convexity Definition A function f defined on a convex subset U of R n is quasi-convex if for every real number h , C − h = { x ∈ U | f ( x ) ≤ h } is a convex set. In other words, for any level h the set of points in the function domain that map to values of the function smaller or equal than h is a convex set. Alternatively, the level sets of the function bound convex subsets from above. Leonardo Felli (LSE, NAB.SZT) EC400 Part II, Math for Micro: Lecture 3 13 September 2010 11 / 23

  12. Example: Quasi-Convex Function g ( x ) ✻ g ( x ) k ✲ x b a 0 Leonardo Felli (LSE, NAB.SZT) EC400 Part II, Math for Micro: Lecture 3 13 September 2010 12 / 23

  13. Properties Theorem Every concave function is quasi-concave and every convex function is quasi-convex. Proof of Theorem First statement: Let x and y be two points in C + k so that f ( x ) ≥ k and f ( y ) ≥ k . Then f ( t x + (1 − t ) y ) ≥ t f ( x )+(1 − t ) f ( y ) ≥ t k +(1 − t ) k = k By definition of C + k therefore t x + (1 − t ) y ∈ C + k and hence this set is convex. Leonardo Felli (LSE, NAB.SZT) EC400 Part II, Math for Micro: Lecture 3 13 September 2010 13 / 23

  14. This is the second advantage of concave functions in economics: concave functions are quasi-concave. Quasi-concavity is simply a desirable property when we talk about economic objective functions such as preferences. The property that the set above any level set of a concave function is a convex set is a natural requirement for utility and production functions. Consider an indifference curve C of the concave utility function U . Implied quasi-concavity means that for every two bundles on C the set of bundles which are preferred to them, is a convex set. Then, given any two bundles, a consumer with a concave utility function will always prefer a mixture of the bundles to any of them. Leonardo Felli (LSE, NAB.SZT) EC400 Part II, Math for Micro: Lecture 3 13 September 2010 14 / 23

  15. Indifference Curve y ✻ C x α x + (1 − α ) z z r ✲ x Leonardo Felli (LSE, NAB.SZT) EC400 Part II, Math for Micro: Lecture 3 13 September 2010 15 / 23

  16. A more important advantage is the shape of the indifference curve is that it displays a diminishing marginal rate of substitution. As one moves left to right along the indifference curve C increasing consumption of good x , the consumer is willing to give up more and more units of good x to gain an additional unit of good y . Leonardo Felli (LSE, NAB.SZT) EC400 Part II, Math for Micro: Lecture 3 13 September 2010 16 / 23

  17. Diminishing Marginal Rate of Sunstitution y ✻ C ✲ ❄ ✲ ✲ ❄ ✲ ❄ ❄ ❄ ❄ ✲ ✲ ✲ x Leonardo Felli (LSE, NAB.SZT) EC400 Part II, Math for Micro: Lecture 3 13 September 2010 17 / 23

  18. Properties: Increasing Function in R 1 Let y = f ( x ) be an increasing function on R 1 . The function is both quasi-concave and quasi-convex. The same applies to a decreasing function. ✻ ψ ( x ) k ✲ x a 0 Leonardo Felli (LSE, NAB.SZT) EC400 Part II, Math for Micro: Lecture 3 13 September 2010 18 / 23

  19. Not true for Increasing Function in R n , n > 1 y ✻ F ( x , y ) = k ′ , k ′ > k F ( x , y ) = k ✲ x 0 Leonardo Felli (LSE, NAB.SZT) EC400 Part II, Math for Micro: Lecture 3 13 September 2010 19 / 23

  20. Other Properties Any monotonic transformation of a concave function is quasi-concave. A single peaked function is quasi-concave (bell-shaped function—i.e. normal distribution). φ ( x ) ✻ k ✲ x a b 0 Leonardo Felli (LSE, NAB.SZT) EC400 Part II, Math for Micro: Lecture 3 13 September 2010 20 / 23

  21. One More Example Consider the following utility function Q ( x , y ) = min { x , y } . The typical indifference curve is L shaped— Leontief utility function. The region above and to the right of any of this function’s level sets is a convex set and hence Q is quasi-concave. Leonardo Felli (LSE, NAB.SZT) EC400 Part II, Math for Micro: Lecture 3 13 September 2010 21 / 23

  22. Example: Leontief Q ( x , y ) = min { x , y } y ✻ Q ( x , y ) = k ′ , k ′ > k Q ( x , y ) = k ✲ x 0 Leonardo Felli (LSE, NAB.SZT) EC400 Part II, Math for Micro: Lecture 3 13 September 2010 22 / 23

  23. Theorem Let f be a function defined on a convex set U in R n . Then, the following statements are equivalent: (i) f is a quasiconcave function on U (ii) For all x , y ∈ U and t ∈ [0 , 1] , f ( x ) ≥ f ( y ) implies f ( t x + (1 − t ) y ) ≥ f ( y ) (iii) For all x , y ∈ U and t ∈ [0 , 1] , f ( t x + (1 − t ) y ) ≥ min { f ( x ) , f ( y ) } You will prove this in class. Leonardo Felli (LSE, NAB.SZT) EC400 Part II, Math for Micro: Lecture 3 13 September 2010 23 / 23

Download Presentation
Download Policy: The content available on the website is offered to you 'AS IS' for your personal information and use only. It cannot be commercialized, licensed, or distributed on other websites without prior consent from the author. To download a presentation, simply click this link. If you encounter any difficulties during the download process, it's possible that the publisher has removed the file from their server.

Recommend


More recommend