credit rating based l evy libor model
play

Credit-rating based L evy Libor model (joint work with Ernst - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

Credit-rating based L evy Libor model (joint work with Ernst Eberlein) Zorana Grbac Department of Math. Stochastics, University of Freiburg Concluding Workshop, RICAM, Linz, 03. 12. 2008 Outline L evy Libor model without risk


  1. Credit-rating based L´ evy Libor model (joint work with Ernst Eberlein) Zorana Grbac Department of Math. Stochastics, University of Freiburg Concluding Workshop, RICAM, Linz, 03. 12. 2008

  2. Outline L´ evy Libor model without risk Credit-rating based L´ evy Libor model Rating-dependent Libor rates Credit migration process Pricing problems Concluding remarks

  3. L´ evy Libor model - notation ◮ T ∗ > 0 fixed time horizon ◮ discrete tenor structure 0 = T 0 < T 1 < . . . < T n = T ∗ , with δ k = T k + 1 − T k ◮ default-free zero coupon bonds B ( · , T 1 ) , . . . , B ( · , T n ) ◮ forward Libor rate at time t ≤ T k for the accrual period [ T k , T k + 1 ] ✒ B ( t , T k ) ✓ L ( t , T k ) = 1 B ( t , T k + 1 ) − 1 , δ k

  4. The driving process Let (Ω , F T ∗ , F = ( F t ) 0 ≤ t ≤ T ∗ , I P T ∗ ) be a complete stochastic basis evy process X T ∗ with values in R d , i.e We work with a time-inhomogeneous L´ ag processs with X T ∗ an adapted, c´ adl´ = 0 and such that 0 (1) X T ∗ has independent increments (2) the law of X T ∗ is given by its characteristic function t ✒❩ t ✓ E [ exp ( i � u , X T ∗ � )] = exp θ s ( i u ) d s I , t 0 ❩ ✏ ✑ θ s ( i u ) = i � u , b s � − 1 e i � u , x � − 1 − i � u , x � F s ( d x ) 2 � u , c s u � + . R d Here b s ∈ R d , c s a symmetric, nonneg. definite d × d -matrix and F T ∗ a L´ evy s measure ( s ∈ [ 0 , T ∗ ] ). Assume the following integrability conditions: ✒ ✓ ❩ R d ( | x | 2 ∧ 1 ) F s ( d x ) | b s | + || c s || + < ∞ sup 0 ≤ s ≤ T ∗ and ❩ ( u ∈ [ − ( 1 + ε ) M , ( 1 + ε ) M ] d ) . sup exp � u , x � F s ( d x ) < ∞ 0 ≤ s ≤ T ∗ | x | > 1

  5. X T ∗ is a special semimartingale with canonical decomposition ❩ t ❩ t ❩ t ❩ √ c s d W T ∗ R d x ( µ X − ν T ∗ )( d s , d x ) , X T ∗ = b s d s + + t s 0 0 0 where W T ∗ denotes standard Brownian motion and µ X is the random measure of jumps of X T ∗ with the compensator ν T ∗ . The semimartingale characteristics of X T ∗ is given by ❩ t ❩ t ν T ∗ ( d s , d x ) = F T ∗ B t = b s d s , C t = c s d s , s ( d x ) d s 0 0 We assume from now on that b s = 0 .

  6. Construction The model is constructed by a backward induction procedure. Assumptions: ( L .1) For every T k there is a deterministic function σ ( · , T k ) : [ 0 , T ∗ ] → R d + , which represents the volatility of the forward Libor rate L ( · , T k ) . We assume that n − 1 ❳ σ j ( s , T k ) ≤ M , k = 1 for all s ∈ [ 0 , T ∗ ] and every coordinate j ∈ { 1 , . . . , d } , where M > 0 is a constant from the integrability condition for X T ∗ . If s > T k , then σ ( s , T k ) = 0 . ( L .2) The initial term structure B ( 0 , T k ) is strictly positive and strictly decreasing in k .

  7. Start by specifying the dynamics of the most distant Libor rate under I P T ∗ (forward measure associated with date T ∗ ) as ✒❩ t ❩ t ✓ σ ( s , T n − 1 ) d X T ∗ b L ( s , T n − 1 , T ∗ ) d s + L ( t , T n − 1 ) = L ( 0 , T n − 1 ) exp , s 0 0 where the drift is chosen in such a way that L ( · , T n − 1 ) becomes a I P T ∗ -martingale, namely b L ( s , T n − 1 , T ∗ ) = − 1 2 � σ ( s , T n − 1 ) , c s σ ( s , T n − 1 ) � ❩ ✏ ✑ e � σ ( s , T n − 1 ) , x � − 1 − � σ ( s , T n − 1 ) , x � F T ∗ − s ( d x ) . R d Next define a forward measure I P T n − 1 associated with the date T n − 1 via dI P T n − 1 = 1 + δ n − 1 L ( T n − 1 , T n − 1 ) 1 + δ n − 1 L ( 0 , T n − 1 ) dI P T ∗ and proceed with modeling of L ( · , T n − 2 ) .

  8. For each k : (1) define the forward measure I P T k + 1 via n − 1 dI P T k + 1 1 + δ l L ( T k + 1 , T l ) ❨ = . dI P T ∗ 1 + δ l L ( 0 , T l ) l = k + 1 (2) the dynamics of the Libor rate L ( · , T k ) under this measure ✒❩ t ❩ t ✓ T k + 1 b L ( s , T k , T k + 1 ) d s + L ( t , T k ) = L ( 0 , T k ) exp σ ( s , T k ) d X , (1) s 0 0 where ❩ t ❩ t ❩ √ c s d W R d x ( µ X − ν T k + 1 )( d s , d x ) T k + 1 T k + 1 = + X t s 0 0 with n − 1 δ l L ( s − , T l ) ✏ ✑ ❨ ( e σ ( s , T l ) x − 1 ) + 1 ν T ∗ ( d s , d x ) ν T k + 1 ( d s , d x ) = 1 + δ l L ( s − , T l ) l = k + 1 and the drift b L ( s , T k , T k + 1 ) is chosen such that it becomes a P T k + 1 -martingale. I

  9. This construction guarantees that processes ✒ B ( · , T j ) ✓ B ( · , T k ) are martingales for all j = 1 , . . . , n under the forward measure I P T k associated with the date T k ( k = 1 , . . . , n ). The t -time price of a contingent claim with payoff X at maturity T k can be calculated as π X t = B ( t , T k ) I E I P Tk [ X |F t ] .

  10. Credit ratings ◮ credit ratings identified with elements of a finite set K = { 1 , 2 , . . . , K } , where 1 is the best possible rating and K is the default event ◮ these ratings correspond to the states of a conditional Markov chain C with the absorbing state K ◮ the default time τ = the first time when C reaches state K τ = inf { t > 0 : C t = K }

  11. Defaultable bonds with credit ratings ◮ defaultable bonds whose credit migration process is denoted by C and with zero recovery upon default: B C ( · , T 1 ) , . . . , B C ( · , T n ) ◮ time- t price of such a defaultable bond can be expressed as B C ( t , T k ) = 1 { C t = 1 } B 1 ( t , T k ) + · · · + 1 { C t = K − 1 } B K − 1 ( t , T k ) , where B i ( t , T k ) represents the bond price at time t provided that the bond has the rating i during the time interval [ 0 , t ] . ◮ Payoff at maturity equals K − 1 ❳ B C ( T k , T k ) = 1 { C Tk = i } = 1 { τ> T k } i = 1 and it holds B i ( T k , T k ) = 1 , for all i .

  12. Libor rates for different credit ratings ◮ The Libor rates for credit rating class i ✒ B i ( t , T k ) ✓ L i ( t , T k ) := 1 B i ( t , T k + 1 ) − 1 i = 1 , 2 , . . . , K − 1 . , δ k We put L 0 ( t , T k ) := L ( t , T k ) (default-free Libor rates) ◮ The forward credit spreads between two successive classes S i ( t , T k ) := L i ( t , T k ) − L i − 1 ( t , T k ) , i = 1 , 2 , . . . , K − 1 . ◮ The corresponding forward credit spread intensities H i ( t , T k ) := L i ( t , T k ) − L i − 1 ( t , T k ) 1 + δ k L i − 1 ( t , T k )

  13. Observe that Libor rates for the rating i can be expressed as 1 + δ k L i ( t , T k ) = ( 1 + δ k L i − 1 ( t , T k ))( 1 + δ k H i ( t , T k )) i ❨ = ( 1 + δ k L ( t , T k )) ( 1 + δ k H j ( t , T k )) ⑤ ④③ ⑥ ⑤ ④③ ⑥ j = 1 default-free Libor intensity between j and j − 1 Idea: model H j ( · , T k ) as exponential processes and therefore ensure automatically the monotonicity of Libor rates w.r.t the credit rating: L ( t , T k ) < L 1 ( t , T k ) < · · · < L K − 1 ( t , T k ) = ⇒ worse credit rating, higher interest rate

  14. Assumptions: ( RBL .1) For every i ∈ { 1 , . . . , K − 1 } and every maturity T k there is a deterministic function γ i ( · , T k ) : [ 0 , T ∗ ] → R d + , which represents the volatility of the forward spread intensity H i ( · , T k ) for the rating i . We assume that γ i ( s , T k ) = 0 for s > T k and that n − 1 ❳ ( σ j ( s , T k ) + γ j 1 ( s , T k ) + · · · + γ j K − 1 ( s , T k )) ≤ M , k = 1 for all s ∈ [ 0 , T ∗ ] and every coordinate j ∈ { 1 , . . . , d } . ( RBL .2) The initial term structure L i ( 0 , T k ) of Libor rates satisfies L i ( 0 , T k ) > L i − 1 ( 0 , T k ) , for all k = 1 , . . . , n − 1 , i.e. B i ( 0 , T k ) B i − 1 ( 0 , T k ) B i ( 0 , T k + 1 ) > B i − 1 ( 0 , T k + 1 ) .

  15. Construction of rating-based Libor rates For rating 1 and all settlement dates T k we model H 1 ( · , T k ) as ✒❩ t ❩ t ✓ b H 1 ( s , T k , T k + 1 ) d s + T k + 1 H 1 ( t , T k ) = H 1 ( 0 , T k ) exp γ 1 ( s , T k ) d X s 0 0 with initial condition ✒ B 1 ( 0 , T k ) B ( 0 , T k + 1 ) ✓ H 1 ( 0 , T k ) = 1 B ( 0 , T k ) B 1 ( 0 , T k + 1 ) − 1 . δ k X T k + 1 is defined as earlier and b H 1 ( s , T k , T k + 1 ) is the drift term (we assume b H 1 ( s , T k , T k + 1 ) = 0 , for s ≥ T k ⇒ H 1 ( t , T k ) = H 1 ( T k , T k ) , for t ≥ T k ). ✏◗ k ✑ 1 Choose drift term in such a way that the process l = 0 1 + δ l H 1 ( t , T l ) t ≤ T k becomes a I P T k + 1 -martingale (Kluge (2005)).

  16. Hence we can introduce the following change of measure ◗ k 1 k dI P 1 , T k + 1 = B ( 0 , T k + 1 ) ❨ 1 l = 0 1 + δ l H 1 ( T l , T l ) := 1 + δ l H 1 ( T l , T l ) . ◗ k 1 B 1 ( 0 , T k + 1 ) dI P T k + 1 l = 0 1 + δ l H 1 ( 0 , T l ) l = 0 P 1 , T k + 1 - forward measure associated with the rating 1 and the settlement I date T k + 1 Use Girsanov’s theorem for semimartingales. Denote δ l H 1 ( s , T l ) h 1 ( s , T l , T l + 1 ) := s ≤ T l . 1 + δ l H 1 ( s , T l ) , Then ❩ t k h 1 ( s − , T l , T l + 1 ) γ 1 ( s , T l ) √ c s d s ❳ 1 , T k + 1 T k + 1 := W + W t t 0 l = 1 is a I P 1 , T k + 1 - Brownian motion and k ✏ ✏ ✑✑ − 1 ❨ e � γ 1 ( s , T l ) , x � − 1 ν T k + 1 ( d t , d x ) ν 1 , T k + 1 ( d t , d x ) := 1 + h 1 ( s − , T l , T l + 1 ) l = 1 1 , T k + 1 =: F ( d x ) d t t P 1 , T k + 1 -compensator of µ X . is the I

Download Presentation
Download Policy: The content available on the website is offered to you 'AS IS' for your personal information and use only. It cannot be commercialized, licensed, or distributed on other websites without prior consent from the author. To download a presentation, simply click this link. If you encounter any difficulties during the download process, it's possible that the publisher has removed the file from their server.

Recommend


More recommend