can probability weighting help prospect theory explain
play

Can Probability Weighting Help Prospect Theory Explain the - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

Can Probability Weighting Help Prospect Theory Explain the Disposition Effect? Vicky Henderson University of Warwick and Oxford-Man Institute & David Hobson (Warwick) & Alex S.L. Tse (Warwick Cambridge) 9th Bachelier World


  1. Can Probability Weighting Help Prospect Theory Explain the Disposition Effect? Vicky Henderson University of Warwick and Oxford-Man Institute & David Hobson (Warwick) & Alex S.L. Tse (Warwick → Cambridge) 9th Bachelier World Congress, New York, July 15-19, 2016

  2. Overview Psychologists have uncovered a wealth of behavioral biases in the way we make decisions under uncertainty → behavioral economics ◮ Thinking Fast and Slow , D Kahneman (Nobel Prize 2002) ˆ o ◦ ◮ US and UK governments have Behavioral Insights Teams/Units to provide policy recommendations Prospect theory is most well known and well supported by experimental evidence of many non-EU theories. (Tversky and Kahneman (1979, 1992))

  3. Experimental & empirical evidence suggests..... Tend to prefer a certain $500 to a 50% chance of $1000 risk averse over gains But prefer a 50% chance of losing $1000 to a certain loss of $500 risk seeking over losses Averse to gambles such as ($110, 50%; − $100, 50% ) loss averse 1 Tend to prefer a 1000 chance of $5000 to a certain $5 1 But prefer a certain loss of $5 to a 1000 chance of losing $5000 overweight tail events Delay realization of losses (relative to gains) - disposition effect

  4. Our Aims We study dynamic stopping models with investors who have prospect theory (PT) preferences. Goal is to show inclusion of probability weighting component of PT can: ◮ Generate more realistic trading behavior than existing PT models ◮ Assist PT in matching the magnitude of the disposition effect

  5. The Disposition Effect ◮ The disposition effect is the stylized fact that investors have a higher propensity to sell a winner (gain relative to purchase price) than a loser (lost relative to purchase price). (Shefrin and Statman (1985)). ◮ Documented for individual investors by Odean (1998), institutional investors, in real estate and options markets. Experimental evidence (Weber and Camerer (1998) and Magnani (2015)). ◮ Shefrin and Statman (1985) propose the disposition effect can be explained by Prospect Theory

  6. Proportion of days with sales producing a given magnitude of return. Using large US retail brokerage dataset. (Thanks to Matthew Burgess (Warwick))

  7. Prospect Theory (Tversky & Kahneman (1979, 1992)) ◮ U a continuous, increasing S -shaped value function defined over gains and losses relative to a reference level R with U (0) = 0. ◮ utility from gains and losses rather than final wealth ◮ risk averse (concave) over gains and risk seeking (convex) over losses ◮ steeper for losses than for gains to capture loss aversion, U ( − x ) + U ( x ) < 0 or U ′ (0+) < U ′ (0 − ) ◮ w ± : [0 , 1] → [0 , 1] a pair of increasing functions with w ± (0) = 0 and w ± (1) = 1. Typically w ± concave on [0 , q ± ] and convex on [ q ± , 1] for some q ± . ◮ probability weighting function applied to CDF to overweight tails of distribution

  8. Tversky and Kahneman (1992) suggest functional forms and calibrate to experimental data: ◮ Value function: � y α + y ≥ 0 U ( y ) = − k ( − y ) α − y < 0 where α ± ∈ (0 , 1). k > 1 governs loss aversion. TK estimate α + = α − = 0 . 88 and k = 2 . 25. Wu and Gonzales (1996) estimate α + = 0 . 5. ◮ Probability weighting function: p δ ± w ± ( p ) = ( p δ ± + (1 − p ) δ ± ) 1 /δ ± for 0 . 28 < δ ± ≤ 1. TK estimated δ + = 0 . 61, δ − = 0 . 69. Wu and Gonzales (1996) estimate δ + = 0 . 71.

  9. 3 1 w + 0.9 w − 2 0.8 0.7 1 0.6 v(x) w(p) 0 0.5 0.4 −1 0.3 0.2 −2 0.1 −3 0 −3 −2 −1 0 1 2 3 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 x p (a) TK (1992) value function (b) TK (1992) weighting with α ± = 0 . 5 , k = 1 . 5 functions with δ = 1, δ + = 0 . 61 and δ − = 0 . 69

  10. Prospect Theory Prospect theory value of cont. random variable Y (reference level centred) is given by (Kothiyal, Spinu and Wakker (2011)) � � E U ( Y ) = w + ( P ( U ( Y ) > y )) dy − w − ( P ( U ( Y ) < y )) dy R + R − If w ± ( p ) = p then E U ( Y ) = E U ( Y ). Denoting by G ( . ) the quantile function of Y , a change of variable & IBP gives � 1 � P ( Y < 0) E U ( Y ) = U ( G ( q )) w ′ U ( G ( q )) w ′ + (1 − q ) dq + − ( q ) dq 1 − P ( Y > 0) 0

  11. Formulation of the Investor’s Asset Sale Problem Investor can choose to sell asset with price P t at time t at any time in the future. Suppose asset price P = ( P t ) t ≥ 0 is a (regular, time homogeneous) diffusion on (0 , ∞ ) with initial value P 0 . Goal of the investor is to choose the best time τ to sell the asset to maximize: τ E U ( P τ − R ) sup where U is value function and R reference level. Note if w ± ( p ) = p , studied by Henderson (2012) (see also Kyle, Ou-Yang and Xiong (2006)).

  12. Formulation of the Investor’s Asset Sale Problem Let s be scale function of P with s ( R ) = 0 such that X t = s ( P t ) is a (local) martingale. Then X t is transformed gains/losses relative to reference and E U ( P τ − R ) = E v ( X τ ) � s − 1 ( x ) − R � where v ( x ) := U . Suppose L := s (0) > −∞ . Let M = s ( ∞ ) ≤ ∞ . We can take X τ rather than τ as the decision variable giving: E v ( X ) sup ν ∈A where � A = { ν : y ν ( dy ) = X 0 = s ( P 0 ) } Skorokhod embedding tells us for every law ν with support on � [ s (0) , s ( ∞ )] = [ L , M ] and such that y ν ( dy ) = X 0 there is a stopping rule τ such that X τ ∼ ν .

  13. Some Related Work ◮ Xu and Zhou (2013) study a similar problem just for gains or just for losses. ◮ We will study the combined gains/losses problem and give additional conditions under which a single point mass on losses is optimal. ◮ Probability weighting introduces time inconsistency (Barberis (2012)). ◮ We focus here on the behavior of a sophisticated investor who can precommit . ◮ Ebert and Strack (2015) study behavior of naive PT agents - with pure strategies they never stop. ◮ Henderson, Hobson and Tse (2015) show this is no longer the only behavior when naive agents can follow randomized strategies. (Saturday 2:50pm)

  14. Two Assumptions w ± are inverse- S shaped: concave on [0 , q ± ] & convex on [ q ± , 1]. Assumption (S-shaped on v ) v is concave on [0 , M ) and convex on [ L , 0] and v ′ (0+) = ∞ Define E ( x ; f , c ) = ( x − c ) f ′ ( x ) f ′ ( x ) f ( x ) − f ( c ) = f ( x ) − f ( c ) x − c as the elasticity of a function f relative to a reference point c . Assumption (Elasticity) a. E ( x ; v , L ) is increasing in x for x ∈ [ L , 0] b. E ( p ; w − , r ) is decreasing in p for 0 ≤ p ≤ min { r , q − } for any r in [0 , 1] . Elasticity Assumption b. holds for all the popular weighting functions - TK (1992), Prelec (1998), Goldstein and Einhorn (1987)

  15. Solving for the Optimal quantile function ◮ Adopt a sequential optimization approach (Xu and Zhou (2013), Jin and Zhou (2008)) by decomposition of X = X + − X − ◮ Optimal X + : ◮ solving a concave maximization problem via a Lagrangian approach ◮ Optimal X − : ◮ solving a convex maximization problem where solution is a 3-point distribution with atoms at L , 0 and some I ∈ [ L , 0] in general ◮ Under assumptions on v ′ (0+) and elasticity of v and w − , the optimal rv only puts one atom on losses. ◮ Combine by finding optimal allocation of probability mass over gains and losses subject to mean constraint

  16. Theorem Under the Assumptions, optimal prospect has a distribution consisting of: ◮ a point mass in the loss regime and ◮ a point mass at some level a in the gains regime, together with a continuous distribution on the unbounded interval ( a , ∞ ) . The optimizer has quantile function G X of the form �� φ  0 dy ( v ′ ) − 1 � � � 1 λ − − X 0 u ≤ 1 − φ  1 − φ w ′ + ( ψ ∧ y )    ( v ′ ) − 1 � � λ G X ( u ) = 1 − φ < u ≤ 1 − ψ w ′ + ( ψ )  ( v ′ ) − 1 � �  λ 1 − ψ < u ≤ 1   w ′ + (1 − u ) (1) for some λ > 0 , φ ∈ [0 , 1] , ψ ≤ q + ∧ φ such that � φ � � 1 λ X + dy ( v ′ ) − 1 0 ≤ ≤ X 0 − L . w ′ 1 − φ + ( ψ ∧ y ) 0

  17. Base Model - TK value & weighting functions ◮ P t follows a GBM dP t = P t ( ρ dt + σ dB t ) (2) ◮ Define β := 1 − 2 ρ σ 2 . For ρ < σ 2 / 2 or β > 0, have s ( p ) = p β − R β and L > −∞ . ◮ TK value and weighting functions with ( α + , α − , k ) and ( γ + , γ − ). ◮ v ( x ) = U ( s − 1 ( x ) − P 0 ) is S -shaped if and only if β ≤ 1, α + < β . ◮ Assumptions on v ′ (0+) and elasticity functions of v and w − all satisfied. Proposition Under the above specification, the problem is well posed if α + /δ + < β . We will work with α + /δ + < β ≤ 1.

  18. Optimal sale strategy involves: ◮ a fixed stop-loss threshold ◮ a random gain level supported on [( v ′ ) − 1 � � λ , ∞ ) w ′ + ( ψ ) 2.4 2.2 2 1.8 1.6 1.4 1.2 1 0.8 0.6 0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1 Quantile function of P τ ∗ = s − 1 ( X ∗ ). Parameters are α + = 0 . 5, α − = 0 . 9, δ + = δ − = 0 . 7, k = 1 . 25, β = 0 . 9, R = 1 and P 0 = 1.

  19. Impact of Probability Weighting Loss Threshold 3.5 Gain Distribution (lower bound and 99th percentile) 3 2.5 2 1.5 1 0.5 0 0.65 0.7 0.75 0.8 0.85 0.9 0.95 1 δ + = δ - Distributional properties of P τ ∗ = s − 1 ( X ∗ ). Vary δ ± on y-axis. Parameters are α + = 0 . 5, α − = 0 . 9, δ + = δ − = 0 . 7, k = 1 . 25, β = 0 . 9, R = 1 = P 0 .

Download Presentation
Download Policy: The content available on the website is offered to you 'AS IS' for your personal information and use only. It cannot be commercialized, licensed, or distributed on other websites without prior consent from the author. To download a presentation, simply click this link. If you encounter any difficulties during the download process, it's possible that the publisher has removed the file from their server.

Recommend


More recommend