a model for a large investor trading at market
play

A model for a large investor trading at market indifference prices - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

A model for a large investor trading at market indifference prices Dmitry Kramkov (joint work with Peter Bank) Carnegie Mellon University and University of Oxford AMaMeF Conference, Vienna, September 1822, 2007 1 / 25 Outline Model for a


  1. A model for a large investor trading at market indifference prices Dmitry Kramkov (joint work with Peter Bank) Carnegie Mellon University and University of Oxford AMaMeF Conference, Vienna, September 18–22, 2007 1 / 25

  2. Outline Model for a “small” trader Features of a “large” trader model Literature (very incomplete!) Trading at market indifference prices Asymptotic analysis: summary of results Conclusion 2 / 25

  3. Model for a “small” trader Input: price process S = ( S t ) for traded stock. Key assumption: trader’s actions do not affect S . For a simple strategy with a process of stock quantities : N � Q t = θ n 1 ( t n − 1 , t n ] , n =1 where 0 = t 0 < · · · < t N = T and θ n ∈ L 0 ( F t n − 1 ), the terminal value N � V T = V T ( Q ) = θ n ( S t n − S t n − 1 ) n =1 Mathematical challenge: define terminal wealth V T for general Q = ( Q t ). 3 / 25

  4. Passage to continuous time trading Two steps: 1. Establish that S is a semimartingale 1.1 ⇔ ∃ limit of discrete sums, when sequence ( Q n ) of simple integrand converges uniformly (Bechteler-Dellacherie) 1.2 ⇐ Absence of arbitrage for simple strategies (NFLBR) (Delbaen & Schachermayer (1994)). 2. If S is a semimartingale, then we can extend the map Q → V T ( Q ) from simple to general (predictable) strategies Q arriving to stochastic integrals : � T V T ( Q ) = Q t dS t . 0 4 / 25

  5. Basic results for the “small” trader model Fundamental Theorems of Asset Pricing: 1. Absence of arbitrage for general admissible strategies (NFLVR) ⇔ S is a local martingale under an equivalent probability measure (Delbaen & Schachermayer (1994)). 2. Completeness ⇔ Uniqueness of a martingale measure for S (Harrison & Pliska (1983), Jacod (1979)). Arbitrage-free pricing formula: in complete financial model the arbitrage-free price for a European option with maturity T and payoff ψ is given by p = E ∗ [ ψ ] , where P ∗ is the unique martingale measure. 5 / 25

  6. “Desirable” features of a “large” trader model Logical requirements: 1. Allow for general continuous-time trading strategies. 2. Obtain the “small” trader model in the limit: � T Q t dS (0) V T ( ǫ Q ) = ǫ + o ( ǫ ) , ǫ → 0 . t 0 Practical goal: computation of liquidity or price impact corrections to prices of derivatives: 1 2 ǫ 2 C ( ψ ) + o ( ǫ 2 ) . p ( ǫ ) = ǫ E ∗ [ ψ ] + � �� � liquidity correction Here p ( ǫ ) is a “price” for ǫ contingent claims ψ . Of course, we expect to have C ( ψ ) ≤ 0 for all ψ and < 0 for some ψ. 6 / 25

  7. Literature (very incomplete!) Model is an input: Jarrow (1992), (1994); Frey and Stremme (1997); Platen and Schweizer (1998); Papanicolaou and Sircar (1998); Cuoco and Cvitanic (1998); Cvitanic and Ma (1996); Schonbucher and Wilmott (2000); Cetin, Jarrow and Protter (2002); Bank and Baum (2003); Cetin, Jarrow, Protter and Warachka (2006), . . . Model is an output (a result of equilibrium): Kyle (1985), Back (1990), Gˆ arleanu, Pedersen, Poteshman (1997). . . 7 / 25

  8. Financial model 1. Uncertainty and the flow of information are modeled, as usual, by a filtered probability space (Ω , F , ( F t ) 0 ≤ t ≤ T , P ). 2. Traded securities are European contingent claims with maturity T and payments ψ = ( ψ i ). 3. Prices are quoted by a finite number of market makers. 3.1 Utility functions ( u m ( x )) x ∈ R , 1 ≤ m ≤ M (defined on real line ): c < − u ′ 1 m ( x ) m ( x ) < c for some c > 0 . u ′′ ⇒ u m has exp-like behavior. In particular, u m is bounded above and we can assume that u m ( ∞ ) = 0 . 3.2 Initial (random) endowments α 0 = ( α m 0 ) 1 ≤ m ≤ M ( F -measurable random variables) form a Pareto optimal allocation . 8 / 25

  9. Pareto allocation Definition A vector of random variables α = ( α m ) 1 ≤ m ≤ M is called a Pareto allocation if there is no other allocation β = ( β m ) 1 ≤ m ≤ M of the same total endowment: M M � � β m = α m , m =1 m =1 which would leave all market makers not worse and at least one of them better off in the sense that E [ u m ( β m )] ≥ E [ u m ( α m )] for all 1 ≤ m ≤ M , and E [ u m ( β m )] > E [ u m ( α m )] for some 1 ≤ m ≤ M . 9 / 25

  10. Pricing measure of Pareto allocation First-order condition: We have an equivalence between 1. α = ( α m ) 1 ≤ m ≤ M is a Pareto allocation. 2. The ratios of the marginal utilities are non-random: u ′ m ( α m ) n ( α n ) = const( m , n ) . u ′ Pricing measure Q of a Pareto allocation α is defined by the marginal rate of substitution rule: u ′ m ( α m ) d Q d P = m ( α m )] , 1 ≤ m ≤ M . E [ u ′ (Marginal) price process of traded contingent claims ψ corresponding to a Pareto allocation α is defined to be S t = E Q [ ψ |F t ] A trading of very small quantities at this price does not change the expected utilities of market makers. 10 / 25

  11. Simple strategy Strategy: a process of quantities Q = ( Q t ) of ψ . Goal: specify the terminal value V T = V T ( Q ). Consider a simple strategy with the process of quantities: N � Q t = θ n 1 ( t n − 1 , t n ] , n =1 where θ n is F τ n − 1 -measurable. We shall define the corresponding cash balance process : N � X t = ξ n 1 ( t n − 1 , t n ] , n =1 where ξ n is F τ n − 1 -measurable. 11 / 25

  12. Trading at initial time 1. The market makers start with the initial Pareto allocation α 0 = ( α m 0 ) 1 ≤ m ≤ M of the total (random) endowment: M � α m Σ 0 := 0 . m =1 2. After the trade in θ 1 shares at the cost ξ 1 , the total endowment becomes Σ 1 = Σ 0 − ξ 1 − θ 1 ψ. 3. Σ 1 is redistributed as a Pareto allocation α 1 = ( α m 1 ) 1 ≤ m ≤ M . 4. Key condition: the expected utilities of market makers do not change , that is, E [ u m ( α m 1 )] = E [ u m ( α m 0 )] , 1 ≤ m ≤ M . 12 / 25

  13. Trading at time t n 1. The market makers arrive to time t n with F t n − 1 -Pareto allocation α n of the total endowment: Σ n = Σ 0 − ξ n − θ n ψ. 2. After the trade in θ n +1 − θ n shares at the cost ξ n +1 − ξ n , the total endowment becomes Σ n +1 =Σ n − ( ξ n +1 − ξ n ) − ( θ n +1 − θ n ) ψ =Σ 0 − ξ n +1 − θ n +1 ψ. 3. Σ n +1 is redistributed as F t n - Pareto allocation α n +1 . 4. Key condition: the conditional expected utilities of market makers do not change , that is, E [ u m ( α m n +1 ) |F t n ] = E [ u m ( α m n ) |F t n ] , 1 ≤ m ≤ M . 13 / 25

  14. Final step The large trader arrives at maturity t N = T with 1. quantity Q T = θ N of the traded contingent claims ψ . 2. cash amount X T = ξ N . Hence, finally, her terminal wealth is given by V T := X T + Q T ψ. Lemma For any simple strategy Q the cash balance process X = X ( Q ) and the terminal wealth V T = V T ( Q ) are well-defined. Mathematical challenge: define terminal wealth V T for general strategy Q . 14 / 25

  15. More on economic assumptions The model is essentially based on two economic assumptions: Market efficiency After each trade the market makers form a complete Pareto optimal allocation . ⇔ They can trade anything with each other (not only ψ )! Information The market makers do not anticipate (or can not predict the direction of) future trades of the large economic agent. ⇔ Two strategies coinciding on [0 , t ] and different on [ t , T ] will produce the same effect on the market up to time t . ⇔ The agent can split any order in a sequence of very small trades at marginal prices. ⇔ The expected utilities of market makers do not change. Remark From the investor’s point of view this is the most “friendly” type of interaction with market makers. 15 / 25

  16. Comparison with Arrow-Debreu equilibrium Economic assumptions behind a large trader model based on Arrow-Debreu equilibrium: Market efficiency (Same as above) After re-balance the market makers form a Pareto optimal allocation . ⇔ They can trade anything between each other (not only ψ )! Information The market makers have perfect knowledge of strategy Q . ⇔ Changes in Pareto allocations occur only at initial time. ⇒ Expected utilities of market makers increase as the result of trade. 16 / 25

  17. Model based on Arrow-Debreu equilibrium Given a strategy Q the market makers immediately change the initial Pareto allocation α 0 to another Pareto allocation � α = � α ( Q ) with pricing measure � P , the price process � S t := E e P [ ψ |F t ] and total endowment M � � α m Σ := � m =1 such that � T Σ 0 − � Q t d � Σ = S t , 0 and the following “clearing” conditions hold true: P [ α m α m ] , 0 ] = E e P [ � 1 ≤ m ≤ M . E e 17 / 25

  18. Process of Pareto allocations Back to our model. Mathematical challenge: define terminal wealth for general Q . Consider a simple strategy N � Q t = θ n 1 ( t n − 1 , t n ] , n =1 where θ n is F τ n − 1 -measurable and denote by N � A t = α n 1 ( t n − 1 , t n ] n =1 the corresponding (non-adapted!) process of Pareto allocations. Remark The Pareto allocation A t contains all information at time t but is not F t -measurable ( infinite-dimensional sufficient statistic). 18 / 25

  19. Process of indirect utilities The process of expected (indirect) utilities for market makers: U m t = E [ u m ( A m t ) |F t ] , 0 ≤ t ≤ T , 1 ≤ m ≤ M . Crucial observation: for a simple strategy Q at any time t knowledge of ( U t , Q t ) ↔ knowledge of A t . ⇒ ( U , Q ) is a finite-dimensional (!) sufficient statistic. 19 / 25

Download Presentation
Download Policy: The content available on the website is offered to you 'AS IS' for your personal information and use only. It cannot be commercialized, licensed, or distributed on other websites without prior consent from the author. To download a presentation, simply click this link. If you encounter any difficulties during the download process, it's possible that the publisher has removed the file from their server.

Recommend


More recommend