optimal investment with state dependent constraints
play

Optimal Investment with State-Dependent Constraints Carole Bernard - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

Optimal Investment with State-Dependent Constraints Carole Bernard SAFI 2011, Ann Arbor, May 2011. Carole Bernard Optimal Investment with State-Dependent Constraints 1/41 Introduction Cost-Efficiency Examples State-Dependent Constraints


  1. Optimal Investment with State-Dependent Constraints Carole Bernard SAFI 2011, Ann Arbor, May 2011. Carole Bernard Optimal Investment with State-Dependent Constraints 1/41

  2. Introduction Cost-Efficiency Examples State-Dependent Constraints Conclusions ◮ This talk is joint work with Phelim Boyle (Wilfrid Laurier University, Waterloo, Canada) and with Steven Vanduffel (Vrije Universiteit Brussel (VUB), Belgium). ◮ Outline of the talk: Characterization of optimal investment strategies for an 1 investor with law-invariant preferences and a fixed investment horizon Extension to the case when investors have state-dependent 2 constraints . Carole Bernard Optimal Investment with State-Dependent Constraints 2/41

  3. Introduction Cost-Efficiency Examples State-Dependent Constraints Conclusions ◮ This talk is joint work with Phelim Boyle (Wilfrid Laurier University, Waterloo, Canada) and with Steven Vanduffel (Vrije Universiteit Brussel (VUB), Belgium). ◮ Outline of the talk: Characterization of optimal investment strategies for an 1 investor with law-invariant preferences and a fixed investment horizon Extension to the case when investors have state-dependent 2 constraints . Carole Bernard Optimal Investment with State-Dependent Constraints 2/41

  4. Introduction Cost-Efficiency Examples State-Dependent Constraints Conclusions Part I: Optimal portfolio selection for law-invariant investors Characterization of optimal investment strategies for an investor with law-invariant preferences and a fixed investment horizon • Optimal strategies are “cost-efficient”. • Cost-efficiency ⇔ Minimum correlation with the state-price process ⇔ Anti-monotonicity • Explicit representations of the cheapest and most expensive strategies to achieve a given distribution. • In the Black-Scholes setting, ◮ Optimality of strategies increasing in S T . ◮ Suboptimality of path-dependent contracts. Carole Bernard Optimal Investment with State-Dependent Constraints 3/41

  5. Introduction Cost-Efficiency Examples State-Dependent Constraints Conclusions Main Assumptions • Consider an arbitrage-free market. • Given a strategy with payoff X T at time T . There exists Q , such that its price at 0 is c ( X T ) = E Q [ e − rT X T ] • P (“physical measure”) and Q (“risk-neutral measure”) are two equivalent probability measures: � dQ � ξ T = e − rT c ( X T ) = E Q [ e − rT X T ] = E P [ ξ T X T ] . , dP T We assume that all market participants agree on the state-price process ξ T . Carole Bernard Optimal Investment with State-Dependent Constraints 4/41

  6. Introduction Cost-Efficiency Examples State-Dependent Constraints Conclusions Cost-efficient strategies A strategy (or a payoff) is cost-efficient if any other strategy that generates the same distribution under P costs at least as much. • Given a strategy with payoff X T at time T and cdf F under the physical measure P . The distributional price is defined as PD ( F ) = { Y | Y ∼ F } { E [ ξ T Y ] } = min { Y | Y ∼ F } c ( Y ) min • The strategy with payoff X T is cost-efficient if PD ( F ) = c ( X T ) Carole Bernard Optimal Investment with State-Dependent Constraints 5/41

  7. Introduction Cost-Efficiency Examples State-Dependent Constraints Conclusions Cost-efficient strategies A strategy (or a payoff) is cost-efficient if any other strategy that generates the same distribution under P costs at least as much. • Given a strategy with payoff X T at time T and cdf F under the physical measure P . The distributional price is defined as PD ( F ) = { Y | Y ∼ F } { E [ ξ T Y ] } = min { Y | Y ∼ F } c ( Y ) min • The strategy with payoff X T is cost-efficient if PD ( F ) = c ( X T ) Carole Bernard Optimal Investment with State-Dependent Constraints 5/41

  8. Introduction Cost-Efficiency Examples State-Dependent Constraints Conclusions Cost-efficient strategies A strategy (or a payoff) is cost-efficient if any other strategy that generates the same distribution under P costs at least as much. • Given a strategy with payoff X T at time T and cdf F under the physical measure P . The distributional price is defined as PD ( F ) = { Y | Y ∼ F } { E [ ξ T Y ] } = min { Y | Y ∼ F } c ( Y ) min • The strategy with payoff X T is cost-efficient if PD ( F ) = c ( X T ) Carole Bernard Optimal Investment with State-Dependent Constraints 5/41

  9. Introduction Cost-Efficiency Examples State-Dependent Constraints Conclusions Literature ◮ Cox, J.C., Leland, H., 1982. “On Dynamic Investment Strategies,” Proceedings of the seminar on the Analysis of Security Prices , 26 (2), U. of Chicago (published in 2000 in JEDC ), 24 (11-12), 1859-1880. ◮ Dybvig, P., 1988a. “Distributional Analysis of Portfolio Choice,” Journal of Business , 61 (3), 369-393. ◮ Dybvig, P., 1988b. “Inefficient Dynamic Portfolio Strategies or How to Throw Away a Million Dollars in the Stock Market,” Review of Financial Studies , 1 (1), 67-88. Carole Bernard Optimal Investment with State-Dependent Constraints 6/41

  10. Introduction Cost-Efficiency Examples State-Dependent Constraints Conclusions Simple Illustration Example of • X T ∼ Y T under P • but with different costs in a 2-period binomial tree. ( T = 2) Carole Bernard Optimal Investment with State-Dependent Constraints 7/41

  11. � � � � � � Introduction Cost-Efficiency Examples State-Dependent Constraints Conclusions A simple illustration for X 2 , a payoff at T = 2 Real-world probabilities: p = 1 2 and risk neutral probabilities= q = 1 4 . 1 1 S 2 = 64 X 2 = 1 4 16 p S 1 = 32 p 1 − p 1 6 S 0 = 16 S 2 = 16 X 2 = 2 2 16 1 − p p S 1 = 8 1 − p 1 9 S 2 = 4 X 2 = 3 4 16 E [ U ( X 2 )] = U (1) + U (3) + U (2) P D = Cheapest = 3 , 4 2 2 � 1 � 16 + 6 162 + 9 P X 2 = Price of X 2 = 163 Efficiency cost = P X 2 − P D , Carole Bernard Optimal Investment with State-Dependent Constraints 8/41

  12. � � � � � � Introduction Cost-Efficiency Examples State-Dependent Constraints Conclusions Y 2 , a payoff at T = 2 distributed as X 2 Real-world probabilities: p = 1 2 and risk neutral probabilities: q = 1 4 . 1 1 S 2 = 64 Y 2 = 3 4 16 p S 1 = 32 p 1 − p 1 6 S 0 = 16 S 2 = 16 Y 2 = 2 2 16 1 − p p S 1 = 8 1 − p 1 9 S 2 = 4 Y 2 = 1 4 16 E [ U ( Y 2 )] = U (3) + U (1) + U (2) P D = Cheapest = 3 , 4 2 2 X 2 and Y 2 have the same distribution under the physical measure � 1 16 + 6 162 + 9 � P X 2 = Price of X 2 = 163 Efficiency cost = P X 2 − P D , Carole Bernard Optimal Investment with State-Dependent Constraints 9/41

  13. � � � � � � Introduction Cost-Efficiency Examples State-Dependent Constraints Conclusions X 2 , a payoff at T = 2 Real-world probabilities: p = 1 2 and risk neutral probabilities: q = 1 4 . 1 1 S 2 = 64 X 2 = 1 4 16 q S 1 = 32 q 1 − q 1 6 S 0 = 16 S 2 = 16 X 2 = 2 2 16 1 − q q S 1 = 8 1 − q 1 9 S 2 = 4 X 2 = 3 4 16 � 1 E [ U ( X 2 )] = U (1) + U (3) + U (2) 163 + 6 162 + 9 � = 3 P D = Cheapest = 161 , 4 2 2 � 1 16 + 6 162 + 9 � = 5 c ( X 2 ) = Price of X 2 = 163 Efficiency cost = P X 2 − P D , 2 Carole Bernard Optimal Investment with State-Dependent Constraints 10/41

  14. � � � � � � Introduction Cost-Efficiency Examples State-Dependent Constraints Conclusions Y 2 , a payoff at T = 2 Real-world probabilities: p = 1 2 and risk neutral probabilities: q = 1 4 . 1 1 S 2 = 64 Y 2 = 3 4 16 q S 1 = 32 q 1 − q 1 6 S 0 = 16 S 2 = 16 Y 2 = 2 2 16 1 − q q S 1 = 8 1 − q 1 9 S 2 = 4 Y 2 = 1 4 16 � 1 E [ U ( X 2 )] = U (1) + U (3) + U (2) 163 + 6 162 + 9 � = 3 c ( Y 2 ) = 161 , 4 2 2 � 1 16 + 6 162 + 9 � = 5 c ( X 2 ) = Price of X 2 = 163 Efficiency cost = P X 2 − P D 2 Carole Bernard Optimal Investment with State-Dependent Constraints 11/41

  15. Introduction Cost-Efficiency Examples State-Dependent Constraints Conclusions Traditional Approach to Portfolio Selection Consider an investor with increasing law-invariant preferences and a fixed horizon. Denote by X T the investor’s final wealth. • Optimize a law-invariant objective function max X T ( E P [ U ( X T )]) where U is increasing. 1 Minimizing Value-at-Risk 2 Probability target maximizing: max X T P ( X T > K ) 3 ... 4 • for a given cost (budget) cost at 0 = E Q [ e − rT X T ] = E P [ ξ T X T ] Find optimal strategy X ∗ ⇒ Optimal cdf F of X ∗ T T Carole Bernard Optimal Investment with State-Dependent Constraints 12/41

  16. Introduction Cost-Efficiency Examples State-Dependent Constraints Conclusions Traditional Approach to Portfolio Selection Consider an investor with increasing law-invariant preferences and a fixed horizon. Denote by X T the investor’s final wealth. • Optimize a law-invariant objective function max X T ( E P [ U ( X T )]) where U is increasing. 1 Minimizing Value-at-Risk 2 Probability target maximizing: max X T P ( X T > K ) 3 ... 4 • for a given cost (budget) cost at 0 = E Q [ e − rT X T ] = E P [ ξ T X T ] Find optimal strategy X ∗ ⇒ Optimal cdf F of X ∗ T T Carole Bernard Optimal Investment with State-Dependent Constraints 12/41

Download Presentation
Download Policy: The content available on the website is offered to you 'AS IS' for your personal information and use only. It cannot be commercialized, licensed, or distributed on other websites without prior consent from the author. To download a presentation, simply click this link. If you encounter any difficulties during the download process, it's possible that the publisher has removed the file from their server.

Recommend


More recommend