notation domestic interest rate r foreign r spot exchange
play

NOTATION Domestic () interest rate: R; foreign: R $ Spot exchange - PDF document

NOTATION Domestic () interest rate: R; foreign: R $ Spot exchange rate $S per 1 Forward rate $F per 1 Basic forex parity relationships 1. Without forward cover, given E (S)=S e , 1 (1+R) $S e (1+R) }Assume cert- or: }


  1. NOTATION Domestic (€) interest rate: R; foreign: R $ Spot exchange rate $S per €1 Forward rate $F per €1 Basic forex parity relationships 1. Without forward cover, given E (S)=S e , €1  €(1+R)  $S e (1+R) }Assume cert- or: } ainty, or risk €1  $S  $S(1+R $ ) }neutrality For no net speculative capital flows: 1+R or (1a)  e S (1) S e S =1+R $ S  R $  R Uncovered interest parity, UIP. [uncertainty+risk aversion  modify UIP.] What, e.g., if R $ < R +  e S S ? 1

  2. 2. Using the forward market: €1  €(1+R)  $F(1+R) with certainty. Given the equally certain: €1  $S  $S(1+R $ ) it's clear that arbitraging implies that: 1+R or (2a) F  S S = R $  R (2) F S = 1+R $ 1+R  R $  R i.e. ( covered ) interest parity , CIP: fwd premium/discount = interest differential. Q. under CIP, why should hedgers use fwd cover, given that spot transactions can  same result? 2

  3. F as a predictor of future S Under certainty , where UIP should hold exactly, S e = S1+R $ 1+R = F, and F (assumed always to satisfy CIP) is the market's expectation of the spot rate. If UIP doesn't hold, an opportunity for profit arises. Assume everything relates to '1 period'. e.g. S e  S1+R $ 1+R , then buy €1 for $S borrowed $. After one period, you have accumulated €(1+R), i.e. $S e (1+R), more than you need to repay the debt of $S(1+ R $ ). Given S e , S (and F) rise. Risky world of risk neutrality  similar result: UIP gives the rational Exp. of the future spot rate: if you held any other, you'd believe riskless profits available. The rational expectation is that such opportunites have been exploited. Then F is the rational expectation. 3

  4. Risk aversion : UIP contains a risk-premium term: e.g. from the $ perspective, the expected appreciation  e S S of the € needs to above the interest differential R $  R for risk-aversion to be overcome and for funds to start to flow into €. Then, F becomes a biased estimate of the future spot rate, even if expectations are rational. Note that bias can also arise because of expectational errors (i.e. non-rational expectations which, unlike RE, will be systematically falsified)  i.e. UIP & hence F may indicate the current market expectation (e.g. under risk neutrality) but if expectations are not rational, then F will not be a rational expectation, i.e will be biased ex post . 4

  5. 3. Purchasing power parity PPP [P=the goods price- level & Ǐ: E (inflation rate)] Under certainty/risk neutrality, to exclude goods-market arbitrage: PS=P $ : i.e. absolute PPP , unlikely with transactions costs & trade barriers, but we may have relative PPP : At t=0 buy one unit of IR goods priced at P, expected to be worth €P(1+Ǐ) at t=1, or (i) $S e P(1+Ǐ). Alter natively €P=$SP at t=0, so buy $SP/P $ US goods. Expected value for t=1: (ii) $(SP/P $ )P $ (1+Ǐ $ ). To exclude arbitrage, (i)=(ii): $S e (1+Ǐ)=$S(1+Ǐ $ ), or S e /S=(1+Ǐ $ )/(1+Ǐ) which in approx. form is: (3a)  e S S  Ǐ $  Ǐ 5

  6. Finally using (1a) + (3a): R $  R  e S S  Ǐ $  Ǐ  (4a) R $  Ǐ $ = R  Ǐ ' Real interest parity ' (I. Fisher): under UIP and PPP, (expected) real returns should be equated internationally.  relevant to Q. of international diversification. Notice that the parity relationships may be put in a slightly different form involving logs: e.g.take logs of (1) S e S =1+R $ 1+R and ln(S e )  ln(S) =s e  s= ln(1+R $ )  ln(1+R)  R $  R. If S & F were € per $1 (rather than $ per €1) then, in all the parity relationships, swap R & R $ . 6

  7. Siegel’s paradox One reason for writing the relationships in log form is to avoid Siegel’s paradox. If E ($ S )=$ F , then you might think that E (€1/ S )=€1/ F : not so, because the expectation of a function of a random variable is not generally equal to the function of the expectation. In fact when the function is convex, as here, then according to Jensen’s inequality, E (1/ S )  1/ E ( S ). So if E ( S )= F , then E (1/ S )  1/ F : i.e. E ( S )= F and E (1/ S )=1/ F can’t both hold. However, if we use E ( log S )= log F , then E ( log 1/ S )= E (  logS )=  E(logS )=  logF=log1/F. See Baillie and McMahon (1989), p. 166; also Harrison, Michael and Patrick Waldron (2011), Finance , Mathematics for Economics and London: Routledge, p. 356ff. and p. 362ff. 7

  8. OVERSHOOTING foreign & domestic bonds Assume: perfect substitutes, +UIP & short run : sticky goods prices & long run : %  P=%  M and PPP. A monetary contraction at t=0  (a) Short run : P constant, M P  , R  (b) Long run : P  , so (i) M P & R  initial values & (ii) by PPP, S  S S(t) R R(t) S 1 R 0 S 0 t=0 t t=0 t (c) Assume rat. exps : S e  in SR & LR. R  in SR only, during which S overshoots its LR (PPP) value. 8

  9. While R  R 0 , depreciation of S after t=0 offsets the additional interest, UIP holding at each t. From UIP, R +  e S S =R $ S e is the LR equilibrium value, by rational expectations, and R $ is given. At each step in the SR, R is above its LR value. R rises initially, capital inflows occur, S rises above S e , and the expected depreciation of S offsets the higher R. As P falls, R falls along a path to its original value, and at each stage is accompanied by a lower S, so the expected depreciation is lower. This may be seen alternatively using a version of UIP in log format: s  s e =R  R $ . 9

  10. The efficient set with exchange-rate risk 2 risky securities, European & US Real returns : Investors IRL US (1) R  Ǐ (3) R+x  Ǐ $ Securities: € $ (2) R $  x  Ǐ (4) R $  Ǐ $ [x   e S S ] -  asset, E (real return) differs  investor - unless PPP,  Ǐ $ =Ǐ+x,  (1)=(3), (2)=(4) - O/W suppose Ǐ $ =Ǐ+x+e, e random with E (e)=0 & payoff is (1) R  Ǐ (3) R  Ǐ  e (2) R $  Ǐ $ +e (4) R $  Ǐ $ Then a given asset has: *Same E (Real return)  investors *More risk for foreign investor. 10

  11. E (Real return) 100% in US IRL investor US investor 100% in IRL  Intuition (& calculus) suggests that if the US asset becomes riskier from an IRL perspective because of increased exchange-rate risk, the IRL investor’s optimal portfolio will involve less of the US asset. An equivalent conclusion applies to the IRL asset/US investor. 11

  12. Possible explanations for home bias: financial & informational frictions -departures from PPP; -institutional barriers, capital controls, etc; -transactions costs & taxes [ but see Tesar & Werner: most investors trade foreign shares more often than domestic: odd, if foreign=excess costs ] Uppal: these are not enough. Other possibilities: -benefits of diversification less than expected? -inefficiency of small stock-markets? -investors diversify via stock in multinationals? (but these are more correlated with other domestic firms, than with foreign) -unfamiliarity of foreign assets? (a 'transaction cost'?) 12

  13. Do investors buy the foreign market portfolio? Kang & Stultz - foreign inv. in Japanese securities: - mainly in large firms: 7% of top size quintile, 1¼% bottom, N=1452 1975-1991; - foreign owned averages 3.8% (equally weighted), 6.4% (value weighted); - i.e. not the Japanese market PF; - foreign PF has  =5.4%, v. 4.8% for J. market PF.; - foreign PF has no extra return. Product market frictions Obstfeld & Rogoff: start by considering the 'traded ' v. 'non traded' classification of goods. (T, NT) Significance: equity claims on either type of firm can be traded, but earnings must be redeemed in traded goods. - so hold a globally diversified PF, but stock in "NT" industries is all held domestically. 13

  14. - i.e. home bias: domestic investors hold all the "NT" stock, & international diversification only applies to the rest of their PFs. Doesn't explain observed biases. For O&R: goods occupy a place in the continuum: Traded v. Non-traded (v. dichotomy). Trade-costs explicity modelled,  model that predicts high & realistic level of home bias. Baxter & Jermann: to hedge human capital risk need short position in domestic traded assets, i.e. % of foreign equity should be higher. Heathcote & Perri: returns to domestic equity covary negatively with labour income, so domestic equity is a good hedge v. labour income risk: 'the international diversification puzzle is not as bad as you think'. Lane & Milesi-Ferretti (2008) [Our] most striking result is that bilateral equity investment is strongly correlated with the underlying pattern of trade in goods. Informational linkages, such as a common language, are also important. 14

Download Presentation
Download Policy: The content available on the website is offered to you 'AS IS' for your personal information and use only. It cannot be commercialized, licensed, or distributed on other websites without prior consent from the author. To download a presentation, simply click this link. If you encounter any difficulties during the download process, it's possible that the publisher has removed the file from their server.

Recommend


More recommend